Heterodox economics movement: Difference between revisions

From Citizendium
Jump to navigation Jump to search
imported>Larry Sanger
m (Economic Heterodox Tradition moved to Economic heterodox tradition: Presumably this is not usually capitalized)
imported>João Prado Ribeiro Campos
(Locke/links)
Line 43: Line 43:
====John Locke, 1632-1704====
====John Locke, 1632-1704====


[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/locke.htm '''John Locke'''] was an empiricist philosopher, [http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/optimist.htm#natural natural law] social thinker and Whig political theorist, John Locke was nonetheless a rather traditional Mercantilist in his economics. Locke developed a ''theory of money'' in his 1692 ''Considerations'', after Child's promoted low interes rate.  
[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/locke.htm '''John Locke'''] was an empiricist philosopher, [http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/optimist.htm#natural natural law] social thinker and Whig political theorist, John Locke was nonetheless a rather traditional Mercantilist in his economics. Locke developed a ''theory of money'' in his 1691 ''Considerations'' <ref name=CONSEQUENCES>[http://socserv.mcmaster.ca/econ/ugcm/3ll3/locke/consid.txt LOCKE, John. ''Some Considerations of the Consequences of the Lowering of Interest and the Raising the Value of Money''. London: London
Printed for Awnsham and John Churchill, at the Black Swan in
Pater-Noster-Row; 1691]</ref>, after Child's promoted low interes rate.  


Locke introduced the concept of ''"money as convention"'' as well as, following [http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/bodin.htm Bodin], the main elements of the [http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/money/quantity.htm ''Quantity Theory of Money''], notably the concept of ''"velocity"''.
Locke introduced the concept of ''"money as convention"'' as well as, following [http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/bodin.htm Bodin], the main elements of the [http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/money/quantity.htm ''Quantity Theory of Money''], notably the concept of ''"velocity"''.


In his 1690 Treatises, he proposes a quite explicit ''labor theory of value''.  In his 1692 ''Consequences'', Locke adheres to a ''demand-based theory of value''. [http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/law.htm John Law (1705)] did much to clarify the confusion between them.
In his 1690 [http://www.lonang.com/exlibris/locke/ ''Treatises''] <ref name=TREATISES>[http://www.lonang.com/exlibris/locke/ LOCKE, John. ''Two Treatises on Government''. London: Printed for Awnsham and John Churchill, at the Black Swan in Pater-Noster-Row; 1698.]</ref> , he proposes a quite explicit ''labor theory of value''.  In his 1692 [http://socserv.mcmaster.ca/econ/ugcm/3ll3/locke/consid.txt ''Consequences''] <ref name=CONSEQUENCES> [http://socserv.mcmaster.ca/econ/ugcm/3ll3/locke/consid.txt LOCKE, John. ''Some Considerations of the Consequences of the Lowering of Interest and the Raising the Value of Money''. London: London
Printed for Awnsham and John Churchill, at the Black Swan in
Pater-Noster-Row; 1691]</ref> Locke adheres to a ''demand-based theory of value''. [http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/law.htm John Law (1705)] did much to clarify the confusion between them.
 
Locke also proposed a theory of property in his 1690 ''Treatises'' <ref name=TREATISES>[http://www.lonang.com/exlibris/locke/ LOCKE, John. ''Two Treatises on Government''. London: Printed for Awnsham and John Churchill, at the Black Swan in Pater-Noster-Row; 1698.]</ref>.  The right to property, Locke claims,  is derived from the labor of those who work it.  More specifically, he perceives that as ''"labor"'' is naturally ''"owned"'' by the person in whom it is embodied, then consequently anything that labor is applied to, is similarly ''"owned"'' by the laborer -- a rather [http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/marxian.htm ''proto-Marxian''] notion.  Locke's ''"natural labor theory of property"'' stands in stark contrast to that of [http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/hobbes.htm Hobbes], who conceived of property merely as a State guarantee, and of [http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/optimist.htm#grotius Grotius], who contended that property emerges from social consen
 
 


===Ricardian Socialism===
===Ricardian Socialism===

Revision as of 19:05, 25 March 2007

Preface

For more information, see: Economics.

The Heterodox Traditions in Economics began when Jean-Jacques Rousseau, a Swiss political philosopher of the Enlightenment and purported father of the French Revolution, wrote his book Discourse on Political Economy (Economie Politique) (1755)[1] which became the entry on the subject in Diderot's Encyclopedie.

Utopians and Socialists

Rousseauvian Socialism

Jean-Jacques Rousseau, 1712-1788

Jean-Jacques Rousseau wrote Discourse on Political Economy (1755), an article which contains no obvious economic theory and is merely a pre-taste of the political philosophy he was to lay out in his Social Contract (1762). His earlier polemical Discourse on Inequality (1754) - which argued that civilization had destroyed man's "natural goodness" and thus was the source on inequality - is prescient of the Marxian doctrine of "alienation".

Rousseau's work had a little direct impact on economics, but exerted a substantial indirect influence. He shared with his fellow Enlightenment philosophers the faith in the existence of a "natural state" of society - which one could thereby extend to social equilibrium and "natural value" concepts - which were very much ingrained in the thinking of the Physiocrats and Adam Smith. His appeal to this state via his "natural man", the "noble savage", is reminiscent of the analogies formed in modern economics.

A thorough pessimist about existing human society, Rousseau recognized that this "natural state" was perverted by "civilization" and that the appetites and motivations of civilized man had been consequently corrupted and constructed by his interaction with society - "Man is born free and is everywhere in chains" as he wrote in his famous opening to the Social Contract [2]

The "natural state", Rousseau claimed, could only be achieved via wholesale social reform which envisioned a collective state with extra-personal dedication to a "General Will"''. Only in such a state, Rousseau asserted, could the true "natural man" exist and be truly free. It is these last observations that make Rousseau the father of Socialism (utopian and otherwise) - and earned him much emnity from later anti-Socialists such as Hayek.

His publications got him arrested and his books were burned throughout France. He ran off to England, being hosted and supported by David Hume where he wrote his polemical Letters from the Mountain [3] Soon he returned to France, where he wandered in poverty until his death in 1778.

Jean-Charles-Léonard Simonde de Sismondi, 1773-1842

Jean-Charles-Léonard Simonde de Sismondi was a French historian, an early socialist and great rival of Jean-Baptiste Say and the [http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/frenchlib.htm French Liberal School. Sismondi was against the capitalist industrial system, which he viewed as being detrimental to the interests of the poor and particularly prone to crisis brought by an insufficient general demand for goods.

His underconsumption thesis was shared by Robert Malthus, and sparked off the General Glut Controversy of the 1820s where their theories were pitted against those of Say, Ricardo and the Classicals.

Sismondi wrote, among other books, Nouveaux principes d'économie politique ou De la richesse dans ses rapports avec la population, Political Economy (1815), Examen de la Constitution françoise (1815)

Utopian Socialism

St. Thomas More 1477-78? - 1535

St. Thomas More, saint, knight, Lord Chancellor of England, author and martyr, was born in London, 7 February, 1477-78; executed at Tower Hill, 6 July, 1535.

Of his writings the most famous is the Utopia [4]

The volume recounts the fictitious travels of one Raphael Hythlodaye, a mythical character, who, in the course of a voyage to America, was left behind near Cape Frio and thence wandered on till he chanced upon the Island of Utopia ("nowhere") in which he found an ideal constitution in operation.

The whole work is really an exercise of the imagination with much brilliant satire upon the world of More's own day. Real persons, such as Peter Giles, Cardinal Morton, and More himself, take part in the dialogue with Hythlodaye, so that an air of reality pervades the whole which leaves the reader sadly puzzled to detect where truth ends and fiction begins, and has led not a few to take the book seriously. But this is precisely what More intended, and there can be no doubt that he would have been delighted at entrapping William Morris, who discovered in it a complete gospel of Socialism; or Cardinal Zigliara, who denounced it as "no less foolish than impious"; as he must have been with his own contemporaries who proposed to hire a ship and send out missionaries to his non-existent island. The book ran through a number of editions in the original Latin version and, within a few years, was translated into German, Italian, French, Dutch, Spanish, and English.

A collected edition of More's English works was published by William Rastell, his nephew, at London in 1557; it has never been reprinted and is now rare and costly. The first collected edition of the Latin Works appeared at Basle in 1563; a more complete collection was published at Louvain in 1565 and again in 1566. In 1689 the most complete edition of all appeared at Frankfort-on-Main, and Leipzig. Lakowski compiled a full bybliography of More's writtings, see: LAKOWSKI, Romuald Ian. A Bibliography of Thomas More's Utopia; Early Modern Literary Studies 1.2 (1995): 6.1-10

John Locke, 1632-1704

John Locke was an empiricist philosopher, natural law social thinker and Whig political theorist, John Locke was nonetheless a rather traditional Mercantilist in his economics. Locke developed a theory of money in his 1691 Considerations [5], after Child's promoted low interes rate.

Locke introduced the concept of "money as convention" as well as, following Bodin, the main elements of the Quantity Theory of Money, notably the concept of "velocity".

In his 1690 Treatises [6] , he proposes a quite explicit labor theory of value. In his 1692 Consequences [5] Locke adheres to a demand-based theory of value. John Law (1705) did much to clarify the confusion between them.

Locke also proposed a theory of property in his 1690 Treatises [6]. The right to property, Locke claims, is derived from the labor of those who work it. More specifically, he perceives that as "labor" is naturally "owned" by the person in whom it is embodied, then consequently anything that labor is applied to, is similarly "owned" by the laborer -- a rather proto-Marxian notion. Locke's "natural labor theory of property" stands in stark contrast to that of Hobbes, who conceived of property merely as a State guarantee, and of Grotius, who contended that property emerges from social consen


Ricardian Socialism

Saint-Simonism

Revolutionary Anarcho-Socialism

Marxist Socialism

Young Hegelians and State Socialism

Christian Socialism

American Populists and Socialists

References

  1. l'ENCYCLOPÉDIE,OU DICTIONNAIRE RAISONNÉ DES SCIENCES, DES ARTS ET DES MÉTIERS par une Société de Gens de Lettres. Mis en ordre & publié par M. DIDEROT, de l'Académie des Sciences & des Belles-Lettres de Prusse;Paris, Briasson..., 1755
  2. ROSSEAU, Jean-Jacques. The Social Contract, or Principles of Political Right. 1762.Translated by G. D. H. Cole, public domain. Rendered into HTML and text by Jon Roland of the Constitution Society.
  3. ROSSEAU, Jean-Jacques. Letter to Beaumont, Letters Written from the Mountain, and Related Writings. .Editor: Univ Pr of New England; 2002; ISBN 1584651644 .
  4. MORE, St. Thomas. Utopia. New York: Ideal Commonwealths. P.F. Collier & Son; The Colonial Press; 1901. This book is in public domain; Internet Wiretap; July 1993. Prepared by Kirk Crady (kcrady@polaris.cv.nrao.edu), first published in 1516.
  5. 5.0 5.1 [http://socserv.mcmaster.ca/econ/ugcm/3ll3/locke/consid.txt LOCKE, John. Some Considerations of the Consequences of the Lowering of Interest and the Raising the Value of Money. London: London Printed for Awnsham and John Churchill, at the Black Swan in Pater-Noster-Row; 1691] Cite error: Invalid <ref> tag; name "CONSEQUENCES" defined multiple times with different content
  6. 6.0 6.1 LOCKE, John. Two Treatises on Government. London: Printed for Awnsham and John Churchill, at the Black Swan in Pater-Noster-Row; 1698.