Neoclassical Schools (1871-today): Difference between revisions

From Citizendium
Jump to navigation Jump to search
imported>Subpagination Bot
m (Add {{subpages}} and remove any categories (details))
mNo edit summary
 
(14 intermediate revisions by 5 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{subpages}}
{{subpages}}
 
{{TOC|right}}
In [[Economics]] the period which begins with the [[Marginalist Revolution]] (1871) and extends until today is called the period of the '''Neoclassical Schools'''.
In [[Economics]], the period which begins with the [[Marginalist Revolution]] (1871) and extends until today is called the period of the '''Neoclassical Schools'''.


==The Marginalist Revolution==
==The Marginalist Revolution==
 
'''[[Marginalist Revolution]]''' <ref name=MARGINREV>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/margrev/margrev.htm The Marginalist Revolution]</ref> was the name given to a movement which took place (almost) simultaneously and independently during the end of the 19th century led by a series of works which lay the foundation for a new concept of Economics and which contributed to the attempt to transform it into an exact science <ref name=NEOCLASSVALUE> [http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/margrev/ncintro.htm#basic Neoclassical Theory of Value: Basic Elements]</ref>.
'''[[Marginalist Revolution]]''' <ref name=MARGINREV>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/margrev/margrev.htm The Marginalist Revolution]</ref> was the name given to a movement which took place (almost) simultaneouly and independently during the end of the XIX century led by a series of works which lay the foundation for a new concept of Economics and which contributed to the attempt to transform it into an exact science <ref name=NEOCLASSVALUE> [http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/margrev/ncintro.htm#basic Neoclassical Theory of Value: Basic Elements]</ref>.


This programatic goal -- to transform Economics into an exact science --
This programatic goal -- to transform Economics into an exact science --
find in the books of [[Carl Menger]] (1871) <ref name=MENGER>[http://www.mises.org/etexts/menger/principles.asp MENGER, Carl. ''Principles of Economics''. New York: New York University, 1976).]</ref> [[William Stanley Jevons]] (1871) <ref name=JEVONS>[http://www.econlib.org/library/YPDBooks/Jevons/jvnPEtoc.html JEVONS, William Stanley. ''Principles of Political Economy''. London: 1871]</ref> and [[Léon Walras]] (1874)<ref name=WALRAS> WALRAS, Léon. ''Éléments d'économie politique pure ou Théorie de la richesse sociale'' Paris: Editor Librairie générale de droit et de jurisprudence, 1976 ISBN 2275012850 <small>First published 1874</small></ref> its decisive moments and it is exactly to designate this multiple explosion the that name ''"[[Marginalist Revolution]]"'' <ref name=MARGINREV>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/margrev/margrev.htm The Marginalsit Revolution]</ref> has been coined.
find in the books of [[Carl Menger]] (1871) <ref name=MENGER>[http://www.mises.org/etexts/menger/principles.asp MENGER, Carl. ''Principles of Economics''. New York: New York University, 1976).]</ref> [[William Stanley Jevons]] (1871) <ref name=JEVONS>[http://www.econlib.org/library/YPDBooks/Jevons/jvnPEtoc.html JEVONS, William Stanley. ''Principles of Political Economy''. London: 1871]</ref> and [[Léon Walras]] (1874)<ref name=WALRAS> WALRAS, Léon. ''Éléments d'économie politique pure ou Théorie de la richesse sociale'' Paris: Editor Librairie générale de droit et de jurisprudence, 1976 ISBN 2275012850 <small>First published 1874</small></ref> its decisive moments and it is exactly to designate this multiple explosion that the name ''"[[Marginalist Revolution]]"'' <ref name=MARGINREV/> has been coined.


===History===
===History===
[[Adam Smith]] (1776), [[David Ricardo]] (1817) and the [[Classical Scholl|Classicals]] <ref name=RICARDDO1>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/ricardian.htm ''The Classical School''. in: The History Of Economic Thought Website]</ref>  (which adopted a cost of production theory of value) struggled to understand what came to be called the paradox of ''"[[value in use]]"'' versus ''"[[value in exchange]]"'', a conundrum that confounded the great economist [[Adam Smith]] (1723-1790), known as the ''"[[diamond-water paradox]]"''. Smith explained in Chapter 4 of Book I of ''Wealth of Nations'':
[[Adam Smith]] (1776), [[David Ricardo]] (1817) and the [[Classical Scholl|Classicals]] <ref name=RICARDDO1>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/ricardian.htm ''The Classical School''. in: The History Of Economic Thought Website]</ref>  (which adopted a cost of production theory of value) struggled to understand what came to be called the paradox of ''"[[value in use]]"'' versus ''"[[value in exchange]]"'', a conundrum that confounded the great economist [[Adam Smith]] (1723-1790), known as the ''"[[diamond-water paradox]]"''. Smith explained in Chapter 4 of Book I of ''Wealth of Nations'':


:::Nothing is more useful than water: but it will purchase scarce anything. . . . A diamond, on the contrary, has scarce any value in use; but a very great quantity of other goods may frequently be had in exchange for it."  
:::Nothing is more useful than water: but it will purchase scarce anything. . . . A diamond, on the contrary, has scarce any value in use; but a very great quantity of other goods may frequently be had in exchange for it."  


Water is essential, diamonds are frivoulous. But the price of diamonds is far higher than that of water. Smith and the [[Classical economy|Classical School]]  had failed to distinguish between ''"[[total utility]]"'' and ''"[[marginal utility]]"'' <ref name=MARGINUTIL>[http://pdfdownload.bofd.net/pdf2html.php?url=http://www.msu.edu/course/ec/201/brown/pim/pdffiles98/utilmax498.pdf''Marginal Utility and Optimization]</ref>. The elaboration of this insight transformed economics in the late nineteenth century, and the fruits of the ''[[Marginalist revolution|marginalist revolution]]'' <ref name=MARGINREV>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/margrev/margrev.htm The Marginalist Revolution]</ref> continue to set the basic framework for contemporary [[microeconomics]].
Water is essential, diamonds are frivolous. But the price of diamonds is far higher than that of water. Smith and the [[History of pre-classical economic thought|Classical School]]  had failed to distinguish between ''"[[total utility]]"'' and ''"[[marginal utility]]"'' <ref name=MARGINUTIL>[http://pdfdownload.bofd.net/pdf2html.php?url=http://www.msu.edu/course/ec/201/brown/pim/pdffiles98/utilmax498.pdf''Marginal Utility and Optimization]</ref>. The elaboration of this insight transformed economics in the late 19th century, and the fruits of the ''[[Marginalist revolution|marginalist revolution]]'' <ref name=MARGINREV/> continue to set the basic framework for contemporary [[microeconomics]].


===The creation of the [[Theory of Marginal Utility]]===
===The creation of the theory of Marginal Utility===
 
The creation of the ''[[marginal utility]]'''s <ref name=MARGINUTIL>[http://pdfdownload.bofd.net/pdf2html.php?url=http://www.msu.edu/course/ec/201/brown/pim/pdffiles98/utilmax498.pdf''Marginal Utility and Optimization]</ref> concept, which flourished during the end of the 19th century, brought the answer to the ''"[[diamond-water paradox]]"'' and has been the theoretical basis for the economic analysis of [[Supply and demand|demand]].  
The creation of the ''[[marginal utility]]'''s <ref name=MARGINUTIL>[http://pdfdownload.bofd.net/pdf2html.php?url=http://www.msu.edu/course/ec/201/brown/pim/pdffiles98/utilmax498.pdf''Marginal Utility and Optimization]</ref> concept, which flourished during the end of the XIX century, brought the answer to the ''"[[diamond-water paradox]]"'' and has been the theoretical basis for the economic analysis of [[Supply and demand|demand]].  


The value of ''[[marginal utility]]'' <ref name=MARGINUTIL>[http://pdfdownload.bofd.net/pdf2html.php?url=http://www.msu.edu/course/ec/201/brown/pim/pdffiles98/utilmax498.pdf''Marginal Utility and Optimization]</ref> is defined as ''"the additional utility perceived by the consumer by the addition of one extra unit of a good"''.  
The value of ''[[marginal utility]]'' <ref name=MARGINUTIL>[http://pdfdownload.bofd.net/pdf2html.php?url=http://www.msu.edu/course/ec/201/brown/pim/pdffiles98/utilmax498.pdf''Marginal Utility and Optimization]</ref> is defined as ''"the additional utility perceived by the consumer by the addition of one extra unit of a good"''.  


For example: a hungry consumer finds an enourmous ''utilitity'' by eating a first loaf of bread. This ''utility'' declines as he keeps eating more units. The 10th loaf of bread represents for him an ''utility'' far smaller than the first one. And the 100th loaf might represent no ''utility'' at all.
For example: a hungry consumer finds an enormous ''utility'' by eating a first loaf of bread. This ''utility'' declines as he keeps eating more units. The 10th loaf of bread represents for him an ''utility'' far smaller than the first one. And the 100th loaf might represent no ''utility'' at all.


===The creators of the concept===
===The creators of the concept===
Demand analysis became possible by the ''[[theory of utility]]'', the mathematical tools of which were first developed by [[Hermann Heinrich Gossen (1810-1858)]] <ref name=GOSSEN>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/gossen.htm Hermann Heinrich Gossen]</ref> (1810-1858) in Germany. However, due to its abstract and mathematical nature, Gossen's work was dismissed by the all-powerful ''[[German Historical School]]'' <ref name=GERHISTSCHLHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/historic.htm German Historical School]</ref>; [[Gustav von Schmoller|Schmoller]] <ref name=SCHMOLLERHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/~het/profiles/schmoller.htm  Gustav von Schmoller, 1838-1917]</ref> dismissed him as an ''"ingenious idiot"''. ''"[[Gossen's law of the saturation of wants]]"'' (''"first law of Gossen"'') stated: ''"The continuance, increase or repetition of the same kind of consumption yields a continuously decreasing satisfaction or pleasure up to a point of satiety"''. "Gossen second law" or ''"the law of diminishing marginal utility"'', which was his most original contribution, presaged the [[Marginalist Revolution|Marginalist Revolution of 1871-74]]. These laws were first propounded in 1854 by [[Hermann Heinrich Gossen|Gossen]], in a rare and little known German book <ref name=GOSSEN1>[http://mitpress.mit.edu/catalog/item/default.asp?ttype=2&tid=8361 GOSSEN, Hermann Heinrich. ''The Laws of Human Relations and the Rules of Human Action Derived Therefrom''.<small>Translated by Rudolph C. Blitz; introduction by Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1983.] ISBN 0262070901</small></ref> and was only rediscovered more than twenty years later by [[Robert Adamson]] (1852-1902), a Scottish Professor of Logic and Philosophy, and reported to the eminent English economist, [[William Stanley Jevons]] who brought it to the attention of the economic profession. Gossen's work was graciously acknowledged by [[William Stanley Jevons|Jevons]] in 1878. <ref name=GOSSENLAW>[http://www.mises.org/easier/G.asp ''Gossen's law of the saturation of wants''; <small>In: GREAVES JR., Percy L. Greaves Jr. ''Mises Made Easier''</small>]</ref> Grossen is considered a proto-marginalist.
Demand analysis became possible by the ''[[theory of utility]]'', the mathematical tools of which were first developed by [[Hermann Heinrich Gossen (1810-1858)]] <ref name=GOSSEN>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/gossen.htm Hermann Heinrich Gossen]</ref> (1810-1858) in Germany. However, due to its abstract and mathematical nature, Gossen's work was dismissed by the all-powerful ''[[German Historical School]]'' <ref name=GERHISTSCHLHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/historic.htm German Historical School]</ref>; [[Gustav von Schmoller|Schmoller]] <ref name=SCHMOLLERHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/~het/profiles/schmoller.htm  Gustav von Schmoller, 1838-1917]</ref> dismissed him as an ''"ingenious idiot"''. ''"[[Gossen's law of the saturation of wants]]"'' (''"first law of Gossen"'') stated: ''"The continuance, increase or repetition of the same kind of consumption yields a continuously decreasing satisfaction or pleasure up to a point of satiety"''. "Gossen second law" or ''"the law of diminishing marginal utility"'', which was his most original contribution, presaged the [[Marginalist Revolution|Marginalist Revolution of 1871-74]]. These laws were first propounded in 1854 by [[Hermann Heinrich Gossen|Gossen]], in a rare and little known German book <ref name=GOSSEN1>[http://mitpress.mit.edu/catalog/item/default.asp?ttype=2&tid=8361 GOSSEN, Hermann Heinrich. ''The Laws of Human Relations and the Rules of Human Action Derived Therefrom''.<small>Translated by Rudolph C. Blitz; introduction by Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1983.] ISBN 0262070901</small></ref> and was only rediscovered more than twenty years later by [[Robert Adamson]] (1852-1902), a Scottish Professor of Logic and Philosophy, and reported to the eminent English economist, [[William Stanley Jevons]] who brought it to the attention of the economic profession. Gossen's work was graciously acknowledged by [[William Stanley Jevons|Jevons]] in 1878. <ref name=GOSSENLAW>[http://www.mises.org/easier/G.asp ''Gossen's law of the saturation of wants''; <small>In: GREAVES JR., Percy L. Greaves Jr. ''Mises Made Easier''</small>]</ref> Grossen is considered a proto-marginalist.


Almost simultaneously [[Carl Menger]] in Austria (1871), [[Léon Walras]] in France (1874-77) e [[William Stanley Jevons]] in England (1871) published their works and became the fathers of the ''[[Marginalist Revolution]]'' <ref name=MARGINREV>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/margrev/margrev.htm The Marginalist Revolution]</ref>.
Almost simultaneously [[Carl Menger]] in Austria (1871), [[Léon Walras]] in France (1874-77) e [[William Stanley Jevons]] in England (1871) published their works and became the fathers of the ''[[Marginalist Revolution]]'' <ref name=MARGINREV/>.


Later [[Alfred Marshal]] <ref name=MARSHALL2>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/marshall.htm Alfred Marshall]</ref> in England, on his  book ''Principles of Economics'' <ref name=MARSHALLPRINC>[http://www.econlib.org/library/Marshall/marP.html MARSHALL, Alfred. ''Principles of Economics'' (1890)]</ref> (1890), greatly extended the concept and recognized that prices are determined simultaneoulsy by ''factors of cost'' and ''factors of demand''. Marshall's theory also analyses the complexes phenomena  ocurring in a price system, with various goods interacting among themselves and affecting each other's prices.  
Later [[Alfred Marshal]] <ref name=MARSHALL2>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/marshall.htm Alfred Marshall]</ref> in England, on his  book ''Principles of Economics'' <ref name=MARSHALLPRINC>[http://www.econlib.org/library/Marshall/marP.html MARSHALL, Alfred. ''Principles of Economics'' (1890)]</ref> (1890), greatly extended the concept and recognized that prices are determined simultaneously by ''factors of cost'' and ''factors of demand''. Marshall's theory also analyses the complexes phenomena  occurring in a price system, with various goods interacting among themselves and affecting each other's prices.  


Carl Menger founded the ''[[Austrian School]]'' <ref name=AUTRIANHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/austrian.htm ''Austrian School'']</ref> (a.k.a ''Viena School''), which was later joined by [[Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk]][[, Ludwig von Mises]] and [[Friedrich von Hayek]]; [[Léon Walras]] worked with the ''[[Lausanne School]]'' <ref name=LAUSANNEHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/lausanne.htm ''Lausanne School'']</ref> while [[William Stanley Jevons]] led the ''[[Anglo-American Marginalists ("Jevonians")]]'' <ref name=ANGLOAMMARGHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/engmath.htm ''Anglo-American Marginalists'']</ref>.
Carl Menger founded the ''[[Austrian School]]'' <ref name=AUTRIANHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/austrian.htm ''Austrian School'']</ref> (a.k.a ''Vienna School''), which was later joined by [[Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk]][[, Ludwig von Mises]] and [[Friedrich von Hayek]]; [[Léon Walras]] worked with the ''[[Lausanne School]]'' <ref name=LAUSANNEHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/lausanne.htm ''Lausanne School'']</ref> while [[William Stanley Jevons]] led the ''[[Anglo-American Marginalists ("Jevonians")]]'' <ref name=ANGLOAMMARGHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/engmath.htm ''Anglo-American Marginalists'']</ref>.
{{Main|Marginalist Revolution}}
{{Main|Marginalist Revolution}}


==Anglo-American Neoclassicism (1871-Today)==
==Anglo-American Neoclassicism (1871-Today)==
==='''Anglo-American Marginalists ("Jevonians")'''===
==='''Anglo-American Marginalists ("Jevonians")'''===
The '''[[Anglo-American Marginalists ("Jevonians")]]''' <ref name=ANGLOAMHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/engmath.htm '''Anglo-American Marginalists ("Jevonians")''']</ref>  refer to early English and American writers between the 1870s and the 1930s who strayed from the Marshallian and Institutionalist schools. Many could thus be deemed ''"followers"'' of [[Willima Stanley Jevons|W.S. Jevons]]; they adopted the ''"mathematical"'' method of reasoning and/or the radical ''"subjectivism"'' inherent in Jevons's revolutionary marginalism.
The '''[[Anglo-American Marginalists ("Jevonians")]]''' <ref name=ANGLOAMHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/engmath.htm '''Anglo-American Marginalists ("Jevonians")''']</ref>  refer to early English and American writers between the 1870s and the 1930s who strayed from the Marshallian and Institutionalist schools. Many could thus be deemed ''"followers"'' of [[Willima Stanley Jevons|W.S. Jevons]]; they adopted the ''"mathematical"'' method of reasoning and/or the radical ''"subjectivism"'' inherent in Jevons's revolutionary marginalism.


=== Clark and the American Apologists===
=== Clark and the American Apologists===
'''[[John Bates Clark]] (1847-1938)''' <ref name=CLARKHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/clark.htm '''John Bates Clark (1847-1938)''']</ref> is best known for developing the ''"[[marginal productivity]]"'' concept and the ''"[[product exhaustion]]''" thesis behind the [[Marginal Productivity Theory of Distribution, which he was the first to develop in 1889. He also developed the theory of marginal utility-based demand independently in 1885. As one of few American economists of the Marginalist school and a prominent apologist for the capitalist system, John Bates Clark was a great opponent of the [[Institutionalist School]].
'''[[John Bates Clark]] (1847-1938)''' <ref name=CLARKHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/clark.htm '''John Bates Clark (1847-1938)''']</ref> is best known for developing the ''"[[marginal productivity]]"'' concept and the ''"[[product exhaustion]]''" thesis behind the [[Marginal Productivity Theory of Distribution, which he was the first to develop in 1889. He also developed the theory of marginal utility-based demand independently in 1885. As one of few American economists of the Marginalist school and a prominent apologist for the capitalist system, John Bates Clark was a great opponent of the [[Institutionalist School]].


The '''"[[American Apologists]]"''' <ref name=AMAPOLOHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/apologist.htm '''"American Apologists"''']</ref> is the term used to describe late XIX Century and early XX Century American ''arch-conservative'' economists and social scientists. Theoretically they hoovered between ''Classical'' and ''Neoclassical''  economic theory; they distinguished themselves in their applied work and policy stance. The most important American Universities system were dominated by strict ''apologists'' for the status quo.  [[Simon Newcomb]]  at Johns Hopkins, [[John Bates Clark]] at Columbia, [[J. Laurence Laughlin]] at Chicago, [[Charles Dunbar]] and [[Frank Taussig]] at Harvard,  [[Arthur T. Hadley]] and [[William Graham Sumner]] at Yale, all defendeded the new industrial age and condemned the unions and populist causes.
The '''"[[American Apologists]]"''' <ref name=AMAPOLOHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/apologist.htm '''"American Apologists"''']</ref> is the term used to describe late 19th-century and early 20th-century American ''arch-conservative'' economists and social scientists. Theoretically they hoovered between ''Classical'' and ''Neoclassical''  economic theory; they distinguished themselves in their applied work and policy stance. The most important American Universities system were dominated by strict ''apologists'' for the status quo.  [[Simon Newcomb]]  at Johns Hopkins, [[John Bates Clark]] at Columbia, [[J. Laurence Laughlin]] at Chicago, [[Charles Dunbar]] and [[Frank Taussig]] at Harvard,  [[Arthur T. Hadley]] and [[William Graham Sumner]] at Yale, all defended the new industrial age and condemned the unions and populist causes.


===Alfred Marshall and The Cambridge Neoclassicals ("Marshallians")===
===Alfred Marshall and The Cambridge Neoclassicals ("Marshallians")===
The '''[[Marshalians]]'''<ref name=MARSHALLINSHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/english.htm '''Marshalians''']</ref> was a group inspired on the work of [[Alfred Marshall]] which relied on practical, intuitive arguments rather than mathematical formalism, taking into account items such as historical time, institutional and industrial structure and real world phenomena, such as uncertainty, money and business cycles.  Their main focus was on  representative conditions. Their work emphasised partial market equilibrium, couching their arguments in terms of "representative" agents, firms, etc. rather than grand, idealized, multi-market general equilibrium systems.
The '''[[Marshalians]]'''<ref name=MARSHALLINSHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/english.htm '''Marshalians''']</ref> was a group inspired on the work of [[Alfred Marshall]] which relied on practical, intuitive arguments rather than mathematical formalism, taking into account items such as historical time, institutional and industrial structure and real world phenomena, such as uncertainty, money and business cycles.  Their main focus was on  representative conditions. Their work emphasised partial market equilibrium, couching their arguments in terms of "representative" agents, firms, etc. rather than grand, idealized, multi-market general equilibrium systems.


===London School of Economics (LSE) and Robbins===
===London School of Economics (LSE) and Robbins===
The [[London School of Economics and Political Science]] <ref name=LSEHET>[http://econ.lse.ac.uk/ '''London School of Economics and Political Science''']</ref> was set up as in 1895 by [[Sidney J. Webb]] and [[Beatrice Potter Webb]], [[Fabian Socialism|fabian socialists]] <ref name=FABIANHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/fabian.htm '''Fabian Socialists''']</ref>, but its early appointments were more conservative: W.A.S. Hewins (later a Tory MP) was its first director, Edwin Cannan, was to head the economics department, the technocratic Arthur L. Bowley headed statistics and liberal theorists L.T.  Hobhouse headed sociology.  
The [[London School of Economics and Political Science]] <ref name=LSEHET>[http://econ.lse.ac.uk/ '''London School of Economics and Political Science''']</ref> was set up as in 1895 by [[Sidney J. Webb]] and [[Beatrice Potter Webb]], [[Fabian Socialism|fabian socialists]] <ref name=FABIANHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/fabian.htm '''Fabian Socialists''']</ref>, but its early appointments were more conservative: W.A.S. Hewins (later a Tory MP) was its first director, Edwin Cannan, was to head the economics department, the technocratic Arthur L. Bowley headed statistics and liberal theorists L.T.  Hobhouse headed sociology.  


Line 60: Line 51:


====Lord Lionel C. Robbins, 1898-1984.====
====Lord Lionel C. Robbins, 1898-1984.====
Lord Robbins was one Englishman who was not a Marshallian but rather a follower of Jevons and Wicksteed. He was one the few economists in England who cared to read the Continental European economists - Walras, Pareto, Böhm-Bawerk, Wieser and Wicksell.  As a result of his Jevonian-Lausanne-Austrian-Swedish influence, Robbins helped to move Anglo-Saxon economics off its Marshallian rails and onto Continental ones.
Lord Robbins was one Englishman who was not a Marshallian but rather a follower of Jevons and Wicksteed. He was one the few economists in England who cared to read the Continental European economists - Walras, Pareto, Böhm-Bawerk, Wieser and Wicksell.  As a result of his Jevonian-Lausanne-Austrian-Swedish influence, Robbins helped to move Anglo-Saxon economics off its Marshallian rails and onto Continental ones.


Line 66: Line 56:


===The Chicago School and Knight===
===The Chicago School and Knight===
 
The ''"[[Chicago School]]"'' <ref name=CHISCHHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/chicago.htm "Chicago School"]</ref> is perhaps one of the better known American ''"schools"'' of economics. The term  ''"Chicago School"''  refers to the approach of the members of the Department of Economics at the [[University of Chicago]] (founded by the oil magnate John D. Rockefeller) over the past century. Also the term ''"Chicago School"'' may be associated with a brand of economics which adheres strictly to ''Neoclassical price theory'' in its economic analysis, ''"free market"'' libertarianism in much of its policy and a methodology relatively averse to  much mathematical formalism. and willing to forego careful general equilibrium reasoning It favors results-oriented partial equilibrium analysis.   
The ''"[[Chicago School]]"'' <ref name=CHISCHHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/chicago.htm "Chicago School"]</ref> is perhaps one of the better known American ''"schools"'' of economics. The term  ''"Chicago School"''  refers to the approach of the members of the Department of Economics at the [[University of Chicago]] (founded by the oil magnate John D. Rockfeller) over the past century. Also the term ''"Chicago School"'' may be associated with a brand of economics which adheres strictly to ''Neoclassical price theory'' in its economic analysis, ''"free market"'' libertarianism in much of its policy and a methodology relatively averse to  much mathematical formalism. and willing to forego careful general equilibrium reasoning It favors results-oriented partial equilibrium analysis.   


In recent years, the ''"Chicago School"'' has  been associated with ''"economic imperialism"'', i.e. the application of economic reasoning to areas traditionally considered the prerogative of other fields such as political science, legal theory, history and sociology.   
In recent years, the ''"Chicago School"'' has  been associated with ''"economic imperialism"'', i.e. the application of economic reasoning to areas traditionally considered the prerogative of other fields such as political science, legal theory, history and sociology.   
Line 74: Line 63:


====Frank H. Knight, 1885-1972.====
====Frank H. Knight, 1885-1972.====
'''Frank H. Knight''', the "Grand Old Man" of Chicago, (irreducibly ''Neoclassical'') was one of the century's the deepest thinker and scholar American economics has produced.  With Jacob Viner, Knight presided over the Department of Economics at the University of Chicago from the 1920s to the late 1940s.   
'''Frank H. Knight''', the "Grand Old Man" of Chicago, (irreducibly ''Neoclassical'') was one of the century's the deepest thinker and scholar American economics has produced.  With Jacob Viner, Knight presided over the Department of Economics at the University of Chicago from the 1920s to the late 1940s.   


His famous dissertation ''Risk, Uncertainty and Profit'' <ref name=KNIGHT>[http://www.econlib.org/LIBRARY/Knight/knRUP.html KNIGHT, Frank H. ''Risk, Uncertainty and Profit'']</ref> (1921), where he made made the distinction between ''"risk"'' (randomness with knowable probabilities) and ''"uncertainty"'' (randomness with unkowable probabilities)is one of the most interesting reads in economics even today.
His famous dissertation ''Risk, Uncertainty and Profit'' <ref name=KNIGHT>[http://www.econlib.org/LIBRARY/Knight/knRUP.html KNIGHT, Frank H. ''Risk, Uncertainty and Profit'']</ref> (1921), where he made made the distinction between ''"risk"'' (randomness with knowable probabilities) and ''"uncertainty"'' (randomness with unknowable probabilities)is one of the most interesting reads in economics even today.


===The Monetarists and Milton Friedman===
===The Monetarists and Milton Friedman===
The ''"Chicago School"'' <ref name=CHISCHHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/chicago.htm "Chicago School"]</ref>, led by the influential economist Milton Friedman <ref name=FRIEDMANHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/friedman.htm Milton Friedman]</ref>, a fierce opponent of the Keynesian economics, led the "Monetarist" movement against the Keynesian orthodoxy in the 1960s and early 1970s.  
The ''"Chicago School"'' <ref name=CHISCHHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/chicago.htm "Chicago School"]</ref>, led by the influential economist Milton Friedman <ref name=FRIEDMANHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/friedman.htm Milton Friedman]</ref>, a fierce opponent of the Keynesian economics, led the "Monetarist" movement against the Keynesian orthodoxy in the 1960s and early 1970s.  


Line 91: Line 78:


===New Classical Macroeconomics and Robert Lucas===
===New Classical Macroeconomics and Robert Lucas===
 
The ''"New Classical school"'' <ref name=NEWCLASSHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/newclass.htm ''"New Classical school"'']</ref>, the ''"modern"'' version of the ''[[Chicago School]]'', is led by [[Robert Lucas]] <ref name=LUCASHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/lucas.htm Robert Lucas]</ref> based on the concept of ''"rational expectations"'' of the 1970s which helped to decisively bury the ''[[Neo-Keynesian]]'' <ref name=NEOKEYNES>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/synthesis.htm Neo-Keynesian]</ref> orthodoxy and inaugurated a new era of [[macroeconomics]] relying on the Neoclassical concept of supply-determined equilibrium explained in  ''"[[Real Business Cycle]]"'' theory.  
The ''"New Classical school"'' <ref name=NEWCLASSHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/newclass.htm ''"New Classical school"'']</ref>, the ''"modern"'' version of the ''[[Chicago School]]'', is led by [[Robert Lucas]] <ref name=LUCASHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/lucas.htm Robert Lucas]</ref> based on the concept of ''"rational expectations"'' of the 1970s which helped to decisively bury the ''[[Neo-Keynesian]]'' <ref name=NEOKEYNES>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/synthesis.htm Neo-Keynesian]</ref> orthodoxy and inaugurated a new era of [[macroeconomics]] relying on the Neoclassical concept of supply-determined equilibrium expalined in  ''"[[Real Business Cycle]]"'' theory.  


Lucas also became famous for the ''"[[Lucas Critique]]"'' (1976) of the use of [[Econometrics|econometric]] models for policy purposes.
Lucas also became famous for the ''"[[Lucas Critique]]"'' (1976) of the use of [[Econometrics|econometric]] models for policy purposes.


===The New Institutionalist Schools===
===The New Institutionalist Schools===
The ''"New Institutionalist Schools"'' <ref name=NEWINSTITUHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/newinst.htm ''"New Institutionalist Schools"'']</ref> to refer to the schools of thought that seek to explain political, historical, economic and social institutions such as government, law, markets, firms, social conventions, the family, etc.  in terms of Neoclassical economic theory.  New Institutionalist schools can be thought of as the outcome of the  [[Chicago Scholl|Chicago School's]]  ''"economic imperialism"'' -- i.e. using Neoclassical economics to explain areas of human society normally considered outside them.
The ''"New Institutionalist Schools"'' <ref name=NEWINSTITUHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/newinst.htm ''"New Institutionalist Schools"'']</ref> to refer to the schools of thought that seek to explain political, historical, economic and social institutions such as government, law, markets, firms, social conventions, the family, etc.  in terms of Neoclassical economic theory.  New Institutionalist schools can be thought of as the outcome of the  [[Chicago Scholl|Chicago School's]]  ''"economic imperialism"'' -- i.e. using Neoclassical economics to explain areas of human society normally considered outside them.


==Continental Neoclacissism==
==Continental Neoclassicism==
 
===The Lausanne School and Léon  Walras===
===The Lausanne School and Léon  Walras===
The ''"[[Lausanne School]]"'' <ref name=LAUSANNEHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/lausanne.htm ''"Lausanne School"'']</ref>, also called the ''Mathematical School'' or the ''Italian School'' refers to the  Neoclassical school of thought led by the Frenchman [[Léon Walras]] <ref name= WALRASHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/walras.htm Léon Walras (1834-1910)]</ref> (1834-1910) and the Italian [[Vilfredo Pareto]] <ref name=PARETOHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/pareto.htm Vilfredo Pareto (1848-1923)]</ref> (1848-1923). It developed the ''general equilibrium theory'', generalizing and extending the applicability of the Neoclassical approach to economics.   
The ''"[[Lausanne School]]"'' <ref name=LAUSANNEHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/lausanne.htm ''"Lausanne School"'']</ref>, also called the ''Mathematical School'' or the ''Italian School'' refers to the  Neoclassical school of thought led by the Frenchman [[Léon Walras]] <ref name= WALRASHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/walras.htm Léon Walras (1834-1910)]</ref> (1834-1910) and the Italian [[Vilfredo Pareto]] <ref name=PARETOHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/pareto.htm Vilfredo Pareto (1848-1923)]</ref> (1848-1923). It developed the ''general equilibrium theory'', generalizing and extending the applicability of the Neoclassical approach to economics.   


Line 118: Line 101:
The Lausanne School evolved over time to a third phase which focused on the overlap of sociology and economics, along the lines of [[François Perroux]] <ref name=PERROUXHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/perroux.htm François Perroux]</ref>.
The Lausanne School evolved over time to a third phase which focused on the overlap of sociology and economics, along the lines of [[François Perroux]] <ref name=PERROUXHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/perroux.htm François Perroux]</ref>.


===The Austrian School and Carl Menger===
===The Austrian School and Carl Menger===
 
The ''Austria School'' <ref name=AUSTRIAHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/austrian.htm The ''Austria School'']</ref> (a.k.a ''Vienna School'') emerged around the pioneer of the [[Marginalist Revolution]] <ref name=MARGREVHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/margrev/margrev.htm Marginalist Revolution]</ref>, [[Carl Menger]] <ref name=MENGERHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/menger.htm Carl Menger]</ref>, at the University of Vienna.   
The ''Austria School'' <ref name=AUSTRIAHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/austrian.htm The ''Austria School'']</ref> (a.k.a ''Viena School'') emerged around the pioner of the [[Marginalist Revolution]] <ref name=MARGREVHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/margrev/margrev.htm Marginalist Revolution]</ref>, [[Carl Menger]] <ref name=MENGERHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/menger.htm Carl Menger]</ref>, at the University of Vienna.   


The ''"First" Generation'' of the Austrian School was composed by the Austrian professors [http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/wieser.htm Friedrich von Wieser] and [[Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk]] <ref name=BAWERKHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/bawerk.htm Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk]</ref>. They spread the Austrian School theories throughout the Austro-Hungarian Empire and trained the next two generations which would count with their disciples [[Ludwig von Mises]] <ref name=MISESHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/mises.htm Ludwig von Mises]</ref> and [[Friedrich von Hayek]] <ref name=HAYEKHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/hayek.htm Friedrich von Hayek]</ref>. [[Joseph Schumpeter]] <ref name=SCHUMPETERHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/schump.htm Joseph Schumpeter]</ref> became a ''Walrasian''. The Austrian School maintained its base in Vienna until the 1930s Before the second World War most of its members moved or were exiled to Great Britain and the United States.
The ''"First" Generation'' of the Austrian School was composed by the Austrian professors [http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/wieser.htm Friedrich von Wieser] and [[Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk]] <ref name=BAWERKHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/bawerk.htm Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk]</ref>. They spread the Austrian School theories throughout the Austro-Hungarian Empire and trained the next two generations which would count with their disciples [[Ludwig von Mises]] <ref name=MISESHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/mises.htm Ludwig von Mises]</ref> and [[Friedrich von Hayek]] <ref name=HAYEKHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/hayek.htm Friedrich von Hayek]</ref>. [[Joseph Schumpeter]] <ref name=SCHUMPETERHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/schump.htm Joseph Schumpeter]</ref> became a ''Walrasian''. The Austrian School maintained its base in Vienna until the 1930s Before the second World War most of its members moved or were exiled to Great Britain and the United States.


===The Swedish School and Knut  Wicksell===
===The Swedish School and Knut  Wicksell===
===[[Paul  Samuelson]], John  Hicks  and the Paretian Revival (1930-40)===
===[[Paul  Samuelson]], John  Hicks  and the Paretian Revival (1930-40)===
The ''"[[Paretians]]"'' <ref name=PARETIANSHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/paretian.htm ''"Paretians"'']</ref> are the Neoclassical general equilibrium theorists of the period 1910-1950 who concentrated on the themes outlined by [[Vilfredo Pareto|Vilfredo Pareto's]] ''Manual of Political Economy'' (1906): namely, the analysis of individual optimization, market efficiency and social optima via classical programming techniques (differentiable calculus, Lagrangian multipliers, etc.).  
The ''"[[Paretians]]"'' <ref name=PARETIANSHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/paretian.htm ''"Paretians"'']</ref> are the Neoclassical general equilibrium theorists of the period 1910-1950 who concentrated on the themes outlined by [[Vilfredo Pareto|Vilfredo Pareto's]] ''Manual of Political Economy'' (1906): namely, the analysis of individual optimization, market efficiency and social optima via classical programming techniques (differentiable calculus, Lagrangian multipliers, etc.).  


Line 135: Line 115:


==The Vienna Colloquium==
==The Vienna Colloquium==
The ''"[[Vienna Colloquium]]"''<ref name=COLLOQUIUMHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/vienna.htm The ''"Vienna Colloquium"'']</ref> was a symposium run by the mathematician Karl Menger (son of the economist [[Carl Menger]]) in the 1930s to bring together many different minds from mathematics but also the physical sciences, philosophy, statistics and economics, that set in motion modern general equilibrium theory from its early roots in the [[Lausanne School]].
The ''"[[Vienna Colloquium]]"''<ref name=COLLOQUIUMHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/vienna.htm The ''"Vienna Colloquium"'']</ref> was a symposium run by the mathematician Karl Menger (son of the economist [[Carl Menger]]) in the 1930s to bring together many different minds from mathematics but also the physical sciences, philosophy, statistics and economics, that set in motion modern general equilibrium theory from its early roots in the [[Lausanne School]].


Line 143: Line 122:


===Tjalling Koopmans and the Cowles Commission===
===Tjalling Koopmans and the Cowles Commission===
With the motto ''"Science is Measurement"'' the ''"[[Cowles Commission for Research in Economics]]"'' <ref name=COWLESHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/cowles.htm ''"Cowles Commission for Research in Economics"'']</ref> was dedicated to the pursuit of linking economic theory to mathematics and statistics. Its main contributions to economics lie in its "creation" and consolidation of two important fields: ''[[general equilibrium theory]]'' <ref name=GENEQUILIBRIUMHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/neow.htm '''Neo-Walrasian General Equilibrium Theory''']</ref> and [[econometrics]] <ref name=ECONOMETRICSHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/metric.htm ''Econometrics'']</ref>.
With the motto ''"Science is Measurement"'' the ''"[[Cowles Commission for Research in Economics]]"'' <ref name=COWLESHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/cowles.htm ''"Cowles Commission for Research in Economics"'']</ref> was dedicated to the pursuit of linking economic theory to mathematics and statistics. Its main contributions to economics lie in its "creation" and consolidation of two important fields: ''[[general equilibrium theory]]'' <ref name=GENEQUILIBRIUMHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/neow.htm '''Neo-Walrasian General Equilibrium Theory''']</ref> and [[econometrics]] <ref name=ECONOMETRICSHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/metric.htm ''Econometrics'']</ref>.


The Dutch-born [[Tjalling Koopmans]] <ref name=KOOPMANSHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/koopmans.htm Tjalling Koopmans]</ref> was the director of the ''"[[Cowles Commission for Research in Economics|Cowles Comission]] from 1948 to 1954, a position he woud alternate with [[James Tobin]] <ref name=TOBINHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/tobin.htm James Tobin]</ref>
The Dutch-born [[Tjalling Koopmans]] <ref name=KOOPMANSHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/koopmans.htm Tjalling Koopmans]</ref> was the director of the ''"[[Cowles Commission for Research in Economics|Cowles Commission]] from 1948 to 1954, a position he would alternate with [[James Tobin]] <ref name=TOBINHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/tobin.htm James Tobin]</ref>


===Kenneth  Arrow, Gérard Debreu and the Neo-Walrasian General Equilibrium School===
===Kenneth  Arrow, Gérard Debreu and the Neo-Walrasian General Equilibrium School===
''"Neo-Walrasian"'' <ref name=GENEQUILIBRIUMHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/neow.htm '''Neo-Walrasian General Equilibrium Theory''']</ref> economics refers to the ''"general equilibrium theory"'' <ref name=GENEQUILIBRIUMHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/neow.htm '''Neo-Walrasian General Equilibrium Theory''']</ref> (often referred to by its acronyms, G.E. or G.E.T.) that emerged in the post-war period.  Rooted in the ''[[Lausanne School]]'' of [[Léon Walras]] and [[Vilfredo Pareto]]; it re-emerged in two forms in 1930s, one more ''"Walrasian"'', advanced by the ''[[Vienna Colloquium]]'', and another more ''"Paretian"'' that was championed particularly at the [[London School of Economics|L.S.E.]], [[University of Chicago]] and [[Harvard University|Harvard]].  
''"Neo-Walrasian"'' <ref name=GENEQUILIBRIUMHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/neow.htm '''Neo-Walrasian General Equilibrium Theory''']</ref> economics refers to the ''"general equilibrium theory"'' <ref name=GENEQUILIBRIUMHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/neow.htm '''Neo-Walrasian General Equilibrium Theory''']</ref> (often referred to by its acronyms, G.E. or G.E.T.) that emerged in the post-war period.  Rooted in the ''[[Lausanne School]]'' of [[Léon Walras]] and [[Vilfredo Pareto]]; it re-emerged in two forms in 1930s, one more ''"Walrasian"'', advanced by the ''[[Vienna Colloquium]]'', and another more ''"Paretian"'' that was championed particularly at the [[London School of Economics|L.S.E.]], [[University of Chicago]] and [[Harvard University|Harvard]].  


The [[Cowles Commission for Research in Economics|Cowles Commission]] merged these two traditions and endowed it with a new mathematical apparatus of axomatic reasoning and ''convex structures'' <ref name=CONVEXHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/math/convex.htm ''Convex Structures'']</ref> (notably the ''"separating hyperplane theorem"'') <ref name=hyperplanehet>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/math/convex.htm#sht ''Separating Hyperplane Theorem (SHT)'']</ref>, creating the ''"[[Neo-Walrasian" school]]'' <ref name=GENEQUILIBRIUMHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/neow.htm '''Neo-Walrasian General Equilibrium Theory''']</ref> in the 1940s and 1950s.
The [[Cowles Commission for Research in Economics|Cowles Commission]] merged these two traditions and endowed it with a new mathematical apparatus of axiomatic reasoning and ''convex structures'' <ref name=CONVEXHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/math/convex.htm ''Convex Structures'']</ref> (notably the ''"separating hyperplane theorem"'') <ref name=hyperplanehet>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/math/convex.htm#sht ''Separating Hyperplane Theorem (SHT)'']</ref>, creating the ''"[[Neo-Walrasian" school]]'' <ref name=GENEQUILIBRIUMHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/neow.htm '''Neo-Walrasian General Equilibrium Theory''']</ref> in the 1940s and 1950s.


[[Kenneth Arrow]] (1951) <ref name=ARROWHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/arrow.htm Kenneth Arrow (1951)]</ref> and [[Gérard Debreau]] (1951 -1954) <ref name=DEBREAUHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/debreu.htm Gérard Debreau (1951. 1954)]</ref> recast the [[Paretian]] theories of the consumer, production and the welfare theorems.
[[Kenneth Arrow]] (1951) <ref name=ARROWHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/arrow.htm Kenneth Arrow (1951)]</ref> and [[Gérard Debreau]] (1951 -1954) <ref name=DEBREAUHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/debreu.htm Gérard Debreau (1951. 1954)]</ref> recast the [[Paretian]] theories of the consumer, production and the welfare theorems.


===Robert  Aumann and the  Edgeworthian Revival===
===Robert  Aumann and the  Edgeworthian Revival===
The ''"Edgeworthian revival"'' <ref name=EDGEWORTHIANHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/edgeworthian.htm ''"Edgeworthian revival"'']</ref> refers to the efforts to study the relationship between a ''Walrasian competitive equilibrium'' and the solutions obtained via alternative exchange process (notably those from  game theory). The mathematical tools of choice that were introduced in this effort in the 1960s and 1970s (measure theory and non-standard analysis) -- were substantially more complex than the tools  economists had been using.
The ''"Edgeworthian revival"'' <ref name=EDGEWORTHIANHET>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/edgeworthian.htm ''"Edgeworthian revival"'']</ref> refers to the efforts to study the relationship between a ''Walrasian competitive equilibrium'' and the solutions obtained via alternative exchange process (notably those from  game theory). The mathematical tools of choice that were introduced in this effort in the 1960s and 1970s (measure theory and non-standard analysis) -- were substantially more complex than the tools  economists had been using.


Line 169: Line 145:
== See also ==
== See also ==
<div class="references-small" style="-moz-column-count:2;column-count:2;">
<div class="references-small" style="-moz-column-count:2;column-count:2;">
* [[Classical economy]]
* [[History of economic thought]]
* [[Economics]]
* [[Economics]]
* [[Econometrics]]
* [[Econometrics]]
* [[Economic Theory]]  
* [[Economic Theory]]  
* [[Econophysics]]  
* [[Econophysics]]  
* [[History of ancient economics]]
* [[History of pre-classical economic thought]]
* [[Keynesians]]
* [[Keynesians]]
* [[Macroeconomics]]
* [[Macroeconomics]]
Line 183: Line 159:


==References==
==References==
<div class="references-small" style="-moz-column-count:2; column-count:2;">
{{reflist|2}}[[Category:Suggestion Bot Tag]]
<references /></div>
* <small> Note: When browsing with FIREFOX it may be necessary to choose "Open link with the external application" to open some .pdf copy protected files</small>
 
==Bibliography==
<div class="references-small" style="-moz-column-count:2; column-count:2;">
* [http://pdfdownload.04340.com/pdf2html.php?url=http://www.rose-hulman.edu/~christ/history/rh351_extended%20bibliography.pdf'''Extended Bibliography''' <small>Rose-Hulman Institute of Technology / Department of Humanities and Social Sciences / K. Christ RH351, Rhetoric of Economic Thought</small>]
 
*[http://socserv2.socsci.mcmaster.ca/~econ/ugcm/3ll3/bentham/usury BENTHAM, Jeremy. ''Defence of Usury''(1787). Hamilton, Ontario: McMaster University.]
 
* [http://mitpress.mit.edu/catalog/item/default.asp?ttype=2&tid=8361 GOSSEN, Hermann Heinrich. ''The Laws of Human Relations and the Rules of Human Action Derived Therefrom''.<small>Translated by Rudolph C. Blitz; introduction by Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1983.] ISBN 0262070901</small>
 
* [http://www.questia.com/PM.qst?a=o&d=97704533 HANEY, Lewis H., Ph.D. ''History of economic thought: a critical account of the origin and development of the economic theories of the leading thinkers in the leading nations''. New York: The Macmillan Company, 1920.]
 
*PARETO, Vilfredo. ''Cours d'Economie Politique''. F.Rouge, Lausanne, 1896.
 
* PARETO, Vilfredo. ''Manual of Political Economy''; Translated By Ann S. Schwier; Edited By Ann S. Schwier and Alfred N. Page Pareto; Publisher: Augustus M. Kelley; 1971.
 
* [http://socserv2.socsci.mcmaster.ca/~econ/ugcm/3ll3/ricardo/prin/index.html RICARDO, David. ''The Principles of Political Economy and Taxation''. 1815 (third ed. 1821). Hamilton, Ontario: McMaster University.]
 
* [http://arielrubinstein.tau.ac.il/Rubinstein-revision.pdf RUBINSTEIN, Ariel. ''Lecture notes in microeconomic theory : the economic agent''. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2006.]
 
* [http://www.econlib.org/library/Smith/smWN.html SMITH, Adam (1723-1790). ''An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations''. London: Methuen and Co., Ltd., ed. Edwin Cannan, 1904. Fifth edition. <small>(Downloadable)</small>]
 
* [http://nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economics/laureates/2001/stiglitz-lecture.html    STIGLITZ, Joseph E. '''''Prize Lecture: Information and the Change in the Paradigm in Economics.''''' <small>Joseph E. Stiglitz held his Prize Lecture December 8, 2001, at Aula Magna, Stockholm University. He was presented by Lars E.O. Svensson, Chairman of the Prize Committee.</small>]
 
* WALRAS, Léon. ''Eléments d'économie politique pure, ou Théorie de la richesse sociale''. Lausanne: F.Rouge, Paris Guillaumin; Paris: Guillaumin & Cie [etc.], et al.; 1889.
 
* [http://www.taieb.net/auteurs/Walras/mech_gf.pdf WALRAS, Léon.''Economique e Mecanique''. (1909). Bulletin de la Société Vaudoise de Sciences Naturelles, Vol. 45, p.313-325. Suivie d'une lettre de Henri Poincaré (1901), et avec une note introductive de G.H. Bousquet (1960). <small>Transcription par Gonçalo L. Fonseca (History of the Economic Thought Website), Courtesy of Mme Paulette Taieb, Université de Paris</small>]
 
</div>
* <small> Note: When browsing with FIREFOX it may be necessary to choose "Open link with the external application" to open some .pdf copy protected files</small>

Latest revision as of 17:00, 24 September 2024

This article is developed but not approved.
Main Article
Discussion
Related Articles  [?]
Bibliography  [?]
External Links  [?]
Citable Version  [?]
 
This editable, developed Main Article is subject to a disclaimer.

In Economics, the period which begins with the Marginalist Revolution (1871) and extends until today is called the period of the Neoclassical Schools.

The Marginalist Revolution

Marginalist Revolution [1] was the name given to a movement which took place (almost) simultaneously and independently during the end of the 19th century led by a series of works which lay the foundation for a new concept of Economics and which contributed to the attempt to transform it into an exact science [2].

This programatic goal -- to transform Economics into an exact science -- find in the books of Carl Menger (1871) [3] William Stanley Jevons (1871) [4] and Léon Walras (1874)[5] its decisive moments and it is exactly to designate this multiple explosion that the name "Marginalist Revolution" [1] has been coined.

History

Adam Smith (1776), David Ricardo (1817) and the Classicals [6] (which adopted a cost of production theory of value) struggled to understand what came to be called the paradox of "value in use" versus "value in exchange", a conundrum that confounded the great economist Adam Smith (1723-1790), known as the "diamond-water paradox". Smith explained in Chapter 4 of Book I of Wealth of Nations:

Nothing is more useful than water: but it will purchase scarce anything. . . . A diamond, on the contrary, has scarce any value in use; but a very great quantity of other goods may frequently be had in exchange for it."

Water is essential, diamonds are frivolous. But the price of diamonds is far higher than that of water. Smith and the Classical School had failed to distinguish between "total utility" and "marginal utility" [7]. The elaboration of this insight transformed economics in the late 19th century, and the fruits of the marginalist revolution [1] continue to set the basic framework for contemporary microeconomics.

The creation of the theory of Marginal Utility

The creation of the marginal utility's [7] concept, which flourished during the end of the 19th century, brought the answer to the "diamond-water paradox" and has been the theoretical basis for the economic analysis of demand.

The value of marginal utility [7] is defined as "the additional utility perceived by the consumer by the addition of one extra unit of a good".

For example: a hungry consumer finds an enormous utility by eating a first loaf of bread. This utility declines as he keeps eating more units. The 10th loaf of bread represents for him an utility far smaller than the first one. And the 100th loaf might represent no utility at all.

The creators of the concept

Demand analysis became possible by the theory of utility, the mathematical tools of which were first developed by Hermann Heinrich Gossen (1810-1858) [8] (1810-1858) in Germany. However, due to its abstract and mathematical nature, Gossen's work was dismissed by the all-powerful German Historical School [9]; Schmoller [10] dismissed him as an "ingenious idiot". "Gossen's law of the saturation of wants" ("first law of Gossen") stated: "The continuance, increase or repetition of the same kind of consumption yields a continuously decreasing satisfaction or pleasure up to a point of satiety". "Gossen second law" or "the law of diminishing marginal utility", which was his most original contribution, presaged the Marginalist Revolution of 1871-74. These laws were first propounded in 1854 by Gossen, in a rare and little known German book [11] and was only rediscovered more than twenty years later by Robert Adamson (1852-1902), a Scottish Professor of Logic and Philosophy, and reported to the eminent English economist, William Stanley Jevons who brought it to the attention of the economic profession. Gossen's work was graciously acknowledged by Jevons in 1878. [12] Grossen is considered a proto-marginalist.

Almost simultaneously Carl Menger in Austria (1871), Léon Walras in France (1874-77) e William Stanley Jevons in England (1871) published their works and became the fathers of the Marginalist Revolution [1].

Later Alfred Marshal [13] in England, on his book Principles of Economics [14] (1890), greatly extended the concept and recognized that prices are determined simultaneously by factors of cost and factors of demand. Marshall's theory also analyses the complexes phenomena occurring in a price system, with various goods interacting among themselves and affecting each other's prices.

Carl Menger founded the Austrian School [15] (a.k.a Vienna School), which was later joined by Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk, Ludwig von Mises and Friedrich von Hayek; Léon Walras worked with the Lausanne School [16] while William Stanley Jevons led the Anglo-American Marginalists ("Jevonians") [17].

For more information, see: Marginalist Revolution.


Anglo-American Neoclassicism (1871-Today)

Anglo-American Marginalists ("Jevonians")

The Anglo-American Marginalists ("Jevonians") [18] refer to early English and American writers between the 1870s and the 1930s who strayed from the Marshallian and Institutionalist schools. Many could thus be deemed "followers" of W.S. Jevons; they adopted the "mathematical" method of reasoning and/or the radical "subjectivism" inherent in Jevons's revolutionary marginalism.

Clark and the American Apologists

John Bates Clark (1847-1938) [19] is best known for developing the "marginal productivity" concept and the "product exhaustion" thesis behind the [[Marginal Productivity Theory of Distribution, which he was the first to develop in 1889. He also developed the theory of marginal utility-based demand independently in 1885. As one of few American economists of the Marginalist school and a prominent apologist for the capitalist system, John Bates Clark was a great opponent of the Institutionalist School.

The "American Apologists" [20] is the term used to describe late 19th-century and early 20th-century American arch-conservative economists and social scientists. Theoretically they hoovered between Classical and Neoclassical economic theory; they distinguished themselves in their applied work and policy stance. The most important American Universities system were dominated by strict apologists for the status quo. Simon Newcomb at Johns Hopkins, John Bates Clark at Columbia, J. Laurence Laughlin at Chicago, Charles Dunbar and Frank Taussig at Harvard, Arthur T. Hadley and William Graham Sumner at Yale, all defended the new industrial age and condemned the unions and populist causes.

Alfred Marshall and The Cambridge Neoclassicals ("Marshallians")

The Marshalians[21] was a group inspired on the work of Alfred Marshall which relied on practical, intuitive arguments rather than mathematical formalism, taking into account items such as historical time, institutional and industrial structure and real world phenomena, such as uncertainty, money and business cycles. Their main focus was on representative conditions. Their work emphasised partial market equilibrium, couching their arguments in terms of "representative" agents, firms, etc. rather than grand, idealized, multi-market general equilibrium systems.

London School of Economics (LSE) and Robbins

The London School of Economics and Political Science [22] was set up as in 1895 by Sidney J. Webb and Beatrice Potter Webb, fabian socialists [23], but its early appointments were more conservative: W.A.S. Hewins (later a Tory MP) was its first director, Edwin Cannan, was to head the economics department, the technocratic Arthur L. Bowley headed statistics and liberal theorists L.T. Hobhouse headed sociology.

The L.S.E. from the very beginning aimed at being an academic teaching-and-research powerhouse. It was one of the group of "new universities" (like M.I.T., Johns Hopkins, Chicago, etc.) founded at the turn of century which eschewed the Oxbridge-Ivy League "gentlemanly education" approach in favor of a more serious academic and technical approach, akin to the Central European model. Like other "new universities", the L.S.E. was keen on raising its profile via academic research.

Lord Lionel C. Robbins, 1898-1984.

Lord Robbins was one Englishman who was not a Marshallian but rather a follower of Jevons and Wicksteed. He was one the few economists in England who cared to read the Continental European economists - Walras, Pareto, Böhm-Bawerk, Wieser and Wicksell. As a result of his Jevonian-Lausanne-Austrian-Swedish influence, Robbins helped to move Anglo-Saxon economics off its Marshallian rails and onto Continental ones.

His tools were the London School of Economics and a famous 1932 essay on economic methodology. He appointed Friedrich A. von Hayek [24], who in turn bred a new generation of English-speaking "continentals" such as Hicks, Lerner, Kaldor and Scitovsky.

The Chicago School and Knight

The "Chicago School" [25] is perhaps one of the better known American "schools" of economics. The term "Chicago School" refers to the approach of the members of the Department of Economics at the University of Chicago (founded by the oil magnate John D. Rockefeller) over the past century. Also the term "Chicago School" may be associated with a brand of economics which adheres strictly to Neoclassical price theory in its economic analysis, "free market" libertarianism in much of its policy and a methodology relatively averse to much mathematical formalism. and willing to forego careful general equilibrium reasoning It favors results-oriented partial equilibrium analysis.

In recent years, the "Chicago School" has been associated with "economic imperialism", i.e. the application of economic reasoning to areas traditionally considered the prerogative of other fields such as political science, legal theory, history and sociology.

The "Chicago School" has had various phases with quite different characteristics. At present, under the term "Chicago School" we can identify various schools of thought: Monetarism in the 1960s, New Classical/Real Business Cycle macroeconomics from the 1970s until today, and more recently, the New Institutionalism, New Economic History and Law-and-Economics.

Frank H. Knight, 1885-1972.

Frank H. Knight, the "Grand Old Man" of Chicago, (irreducibly Neoclassical) was one of the century's the deepest thinker and scholar American economics has produced. With Jacob Viner, Knight presided over the Department of Economics at the University of Chicago from the 1920s to the late 1940s.

His famous dissertation Risk, Uncertainty and Profit [26] (1921), where he made made the distinction between "risk" (randomness with knowable probabilities) and "uncertainty" (randomness with unknowable probabilities)is one of the most interesting reads in economics even today.

The Monetarists and Milton Friedman

The "Chicago School" [25], led by the influential economist Milton Friedman [27], a fierce opponent of the Keynesian economics, led the "Monetarist" movement against the Keynesian orthodoxy in the 1960s and early 1970s.

Friedman's criticisms [28] of Keynesian theory began with his attack on the IS-LM [29] dichotomy in his "restatement" [30] of the Quantity Theory of Money [31] in 1956 -- effectively, reminding Keynesians that "money matters".

Friedman (1968) exposed the apparent breakdown of the "Phillips Curve" [32] relationship in the 1970s, proposing to replace it with a "Natural Rate of Unemployment" (NRU) - a concept later formalized in more detail by the "New Classicals" [33].

Friedman argued that government discretionary "fine-tuning" of the economy, as had been proposed by Keynesians, ought to be replaced with iron "rules" of policy - notably his famous "money supply growth" rule. He also wrote several books advocating laissez-faire.

New Classical Macroeconomics and Robert Lucas

The "New Classical school" [33], the "modern" version of the Chicago School, is led by Robert Lucas [34] based on the concept of "rational expectations" of the 1970s which helped to decisively bury the Neo-Keynesian [35] orthodoxy and inaugurated a new era of macroeconomics relying on the Neoclassical concept of supply-determined equilibrium explained in "Real Business Cycle" theory.

Lucas also became famous for the "Lucas Critique" (1976) of the use of econometric models for policy purposes.

The New Institutionalist Schools

The "New Institutionalist Schools" [36] to refer to the schools of thought that seek to explain political, historical, economic and social institutions such as government, law, markets, firms, social conventions, the family, etc. in terms of Neoclassical economic theory. New Institutionalist schools can be thought of as the outcome of the Chicago School's "economic imperialism" -- i.e. using Neoclassical economics to explain areas of human society normally considered outside them.

Continental Neoclassicism

The Lausanne School and Léon Walras

The "Lausanne School" [16], also called the Mathematical School or the Italian School refers to the Neoclassical school of thought led by the Frenchman Léon Walras [37] (1834-1910) and the Italian Vilfredo Pareto [38] (1848-1923). It developed the general equilibrium theory, generalizing and extending the applicability of the Neoclassical approach to economics.

One can distinguish between the early "Walrasian" and the later "Paretian" stages of the "Lausanne School" [16]. The core of their theories were identical but their emphasis and mode of analysis were different.

Walras fundamental tool of analysis was a system of simultaneous market demand and supply equations. He was mainly interested in analyzing grand themes: the existence of an equilibrium solution to a this system, the stability of that equilibrium, the incorporation of capital and growth and the introduction of money.

Vilfredo Pareto, Enrico Barone and Giovanni Antonelli, his Italian disciples, were particularly interested in the "microfoundations" of general equilibrium systems, the relationship between decision-making households and firms and the resulting general equilibrium. Consequently, the research focus of the Lausanne School moved in a different direction.

As this new direction was announced most prominently in Vilfredo Pareto's Cours d'Économie politique (1896-7) [39] and in his Manual of Political Economy (1906) [40] this was the "Paretian" phase.

The Paretians saw the problem as one of ensuring the compatibility of the individual incentives and constraints of consumers and producers in equilibrium. Their tools were the differential calculus and Lagrangian multipliers. Using advanced mathematics, they constructed a rather grand "Paretian general equilibrium system", a system of equations, where the agent-theoretic microfoundations were starkly brought to the fore. They replaced all the grand themes of Walras with a single new one of their own: the efficiency and social optimality of equilibrium.

The Lausanne School evolved over time to a third phase which focused on the overlap of sociology and economics, along the lines of François Perroux [41].

The Austrian School and Carl Menger

The Austria School [42] (a.k.a Vienna School) emerged around the pioneer of the Marginalist Revolution [43], Carl Menger [44], at the University of Vienna.

The "First" Generation of the Austrian School was composed by the Austrian professors Friedrich von Wieser and Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk [45]. They spread the Austrian School theories throughout the Austro-Hungarian Empire and trained the next two generations which would count with their disciples Ludwig von Mises [46] and Friedrich von Hayek [24]. Joseph Schumpeter [47] became a Walrasian. The Austrian School maintained its base in Vienna until the 1930s Before the second World War most of its members moved or were exiled to Great Britain and the United States.

The Swedish School and Knut Wicksell

Paul Samuelson, John Hicks and the Paretian Revival (1930-40)

The "Paretians" [48] are the Neoclassical general equilibrium theorists of the period 1910-1950 who concentrated on the themes outlined by Vilfredo Pareto's Manual of Political Economy (1906): namely, the analysis of individual optimization, market efficiency and social optima via classical programming techniques (differentiable calculus, Lagrangian multipliers, etc.).

The Paretian Revival reached its apex during the 1930s and 1940s. John Hicks [49], Paul Samuelson [50], Abba Lerner [51], Oskar Lange [52], Maurice Allais [53] and Harold Hotelling [54] led the way.

The Paretian Revival represents the first time that the work of the "Lausanne School" [16] began breaking the English-language barrier.

The Vienna Colloquium

The "Vienna Colloquium"[55] was a symposium run by the mathematician Karl Menger (son of the economist Carl Menger) in the 1930s to bring together many different minds from mathematics but also the physical sciences, philosophy, statistics and economics, that set in motion modern general equilibrium theory from its early roots in the Lausanne School.

Among the participants in the Colloquium, besides Karl Menger, was the banker Karl Schlesing Oskar Morgenstern, the polymath John von Neumann [56] and the statistician Abraham Wald [57] . Other participants included assorted Viennese physicists and mathematicians like Kurt Gödel [58].

During the 1930s Menger collected and published the proceedings of the Colloquium as the "Ergebnisse eines mathematischen Kolloquiums" [59]

Tjalling Koopmans and the Cowles Commission

With the motto "Science is Measurement" the "Cowles Commission for Research in Economics" [60] was dedicated to the pursuit of linking economic theory to mathematics and statistics. Its main contributions to economics lie in its "creation" and consolidation of two important fields: general equilibrium theory [61] and econometrics [62].

The Dutch-born Tjalling Koopmans [63] was the director of the "Cowles Commission from 1948 to 1954, a position he would alternate with James Tobin [64]

Kenneth Arrow, Gérard Debreu and the Neo-Walrasian General Equilibrium School

"Neo-Walrasian" [61] economics refers to the "general equilibrium theory" [61] (often referred to by its acronyms, G.E. or G.E.T.) that emerged in the post-war period. Rooted in the Lausanne School of Léon Walras and Vilfredo Pareto; it re-emerged in two forms in 1930s, one more "Walrasian", advanced by the Vienna Colloquium, and another more "Paretian" that was championed particularly at the L.S.E., University of Chicago and Harvard.

The Cowles Commission merged these two traditions and endowed it with a new mathematical apparatus of axiomatic reasoning and convex structures [65] (notably the "separating hyperplane theorem") [66], creating the "Neo-Walrasian" school [61] in the 1940s and 1950s.

Kenneth Arrow (1951) [67] and Gérard Debreau (1951 -1954) [68] recast the Paretian theories of the consumer, production and the welfare theorems.

Robert Aumann and the Edgeworthian Revival

The "Edgeworthian revival" [69] refers to the efforts to study the relationship between a Walrasian competitive equilibrium and the solutions obtained via alternative exchange process (notably those from game theory). The mathematical tools of choice that were introduced in this effort in the 1960s and 1970s (measure theory and non-standard analysis) -- were substantially more complex than the tools economists had been using.

The main goal of this group of economists was to try and prove the "Edgeworth's conjecture" [70].

Robert Aumann [71] proved (1964) the equivalence of the Edgeworthian core [72] and the Walrasian equilibria [73] when we have a continuum (uncountably infinite number) of agents. This "new" definition of "perfect competition" [74] brought measure theory [75]

Edited by -- notably Lyapunov's Theorem [76] -- into economics (Lyapunov's theorem asserts that the range of a non-atomic totally finite vector-valued measure is both convex and compact).

For more information, see: Economics.


See also

References

  1. 1.0 1.1 1.2 1.3 The Marginalist Revolution
  2. Neoclassical Theory of Value: Basic Elements
  3. MENGER, Carl. Principles of Economics. New York: New York University, 1976).
  4. JEVONS, William Stanley. Principles of Political Economy. London: 1871
  5. WALRAS, Léon. Éléments d'économie politique pure ou Théorie de la richesse sociale Paris: Editor Librairie générale de droit et de jurisprudence, 1976 ISBN 2275012850 First published 1874
  6. The Classical School. in: The History Of Economic Thought Website
  7. 7.0 7.1 7.2 Marginal Utility and Optimization
  8. Hermann Heinrich Gossen
  9. German Historical School
  10. Gustav von Schmoller, 1838-1917
  11. GOSSEN, Hermann Heinrich. The Laws of Human Relations and the Rules of Human Action Derived Therefrom.Translated by Rudolph C. Blitz; introduction by Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1983. ISBN 0262070901
  12. Gossen's law of the saturation of wants; In: GREAVES JR., Percy L. Greaves Jr. Mises Made Easier
  13. Alfred Marshall
  14. MARSHALL, Alfred. Principles of Economics (1890)
  15. Austrian School
  16. 16.0 16.1 16.2 16.3 Lausanne School Cite error: Invalid <ref> tag; name "LAUSANNEHET" defined multiple times with different content Cite error: Invalid <ref> tag; name "LAUSANNEHET" defined multiple times with different content Cite error: Invalid <ref> tag; name "LAUSANNEHET" defined multiple times with different content
  17. Anglo-American Marginalists
  18. Anglo-American Marginalists ("Jevonians")
  19. John Bates Clark (1847-1938)
  20. "American Apologists"
  21. Marshalians
  22. London School of Economics and Political Science
  23. Fabian Socialists
  24. 24.0 24.1 Friedrich A. von Hayek Cite error: Invalid <ref> tag; name "HAYEKHET" defined multiple times with different content
  25. 25.0 25.1 "Chicago School"
  26. KNIGHT, Frank H. Risk, Uncertainty and Profit
  27. Milton Friedman
  28. The Inflation Acceleration Controversy
  29. The Hicks-Hansen IS-LM Model
  30. The Monetarist Transmission Mechanism
  31. The Quantity Theory of Money
  32. "Phillips Curve"
  33. 33.0 33.1 "New Classical school"
  34. Robert Lucas
  35. Neo-Keynesian
  36. "New Institutionalist Schools"
  37. Léon Walras (1834-1910)
  38. Vilfredo Pareto (1848-1923)
  39. PARETO, Vilfredo. Cours d'Economie Politique. F.Rouge, Lausanne, 1896
  40. PARETO, Vilfredo. Manual of Political Economy; Translated By Ann S. Schwier; Edited By Ann S. Schwier and Alfred N. Page Pareto; Publisher: Augustus M. Kelley; 1971
  41. François Perroux
  42. The Austria School
  43. Marginalist Revolution
  44. Carl Menger
  45. Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk
  46. Ludwig von Mises
  47. Joseph Schumpeter
  48. "Paretians"
  49. John Hicks
  50. Paul Samuelson
  51. Abba Lerner
  52. Oskar Lange
  53. Maurice Allais
  54. Harold Hotelling
  55. The "Vienna Colloquium"
  56. John von Neumann
  57. Abraham Wald
  58. Kurt Gödel
  59. GÖDEL, Kurt et al. Ergebnisse eines mathematischen Kolloquiums. Unter Mitwirkung von K. Gödel und G. Nöbeling herausgegeben von K. Menger. Heft 1 (1931), Heft 2 (1932). B. G. Teubner, Leipzig und Wien. Preis RM 2 Journal Monatshefte für Mathematik Publisher Springer Wien
  60. "Cowles Commission for Research in Economics"
  61. 61.0 61.1 61.2 61.3 Neo-Walrasian General Equilibrium Theory
  62. Econometrics
  63. Tjalling Koopmans
  64. James Tobin
  65. Convex Structures
  66. Separating Hyperplane Theorem (SHT)
  67. Kenneth Arrow (1951)
  68. Gérard Debreau (1951. 1954)
  69. "Edgeworthian revival"
  70. "Edgeworth's conjecture"
  71. Robert Aumann
  72. Competition and the Edgeworthian core
  73. Walrasian equilibria
  74. Perfect Competition
  75. ARROW, K. J. Arrow, INTRILIGATOR, M.D., HILDENBRAND, W., and SONNENSCHEIN, H., editors. Handbook of Mathematical Economics
  76. Basic Lyapunov theory