Macroeconomics: Difference between revisions

From Citizendium
Jump to navigation Jump to search
imported>Nick Gardner
mNo edit summary
 
(95 intermediate revisions by 8 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
Macroeconomics is the study of the economy viewed as a single interactive system.  It is concerned, not with individual transactions,  but with economy-wide aggregates including national income, the rate of inflation and the unemployment rate.  At the theoretical level it  seeks  to explain how national income grows, how it fluctuates and what then happens to prices and unemployment.  At the positive level it tests competing theories against the evidence provided by economic statistics,  and it estimates the numerical relationships required to construct forecasting models. At the normative level it considers what policies would serve to promote economic stability and growth and full employment.
{{subpages}}
'''Macroeconomics''' is the study of the national [[economy]] viewed as a single interactive system.  It is concerned, not with individual transactions,  but with economy-wide aggregates, including national income, the rate of inflation and the unemployment rate.  At the theoretical level it  seeks  to explain how national income grows, how it fluctuates and what then happens to prices and unemployment.  At the positive level it tests competing theories against the evidence provided by economic statistics,  and it estimates the numerical relationships required to construct forecasting models. At the application level it considers what policies would serve to promote economic stability and growth and full employment.


Since a national economy is too complex to analyse for those purposes,  macroeconomics uses  simplified versions, or “economic models”  which ignore those  components  that are thought to have relatively little influence upon the question under consideration.  The initial  procedure  postulates the way that the components of the system interact and deduces from those postulated relationships,  how the system as a whole may be expected to behave.  That deductive process is normally followed by the use of  evidence and inductive reasoning to  test, either the relationships  themselves,  or the deduced behaviour of the system.
Since a national economy is too complex to analyse for those purposes,  macroeconomics uses  simplified versions which ignore those  components  that are thought to have relatively little influence upon the question under consideration.  The initial  procedure  postulates the way that the components of the system interact and deduces from those postulated relationships,  how the system as a whole may be expected to behave.  That deductive process is normally followed by the use of  evidence and inductive reasoning to  test, either the relationships  themselves,  or the deduced behaviour of the system.


This article is concerned with the concepts and theories of economics. An account of the way in which those theories developed, and of the contributions of those responsible, is available in the article on the [[History of Economic Thought]].  
''This article summarises the main concepts and theories of macroeconomics without attempting to attribute them to those responsible; and some of its later paragraphs are confined to what is believed to be the consensus view among professional economists. Readers seeking an account of how, and by whom, those and other theories were developed should consult the article on the [[history of economic thought]].''
 
Some of the latter paragraphs of this article present the current consensus view among economists. There are, however, a number of well-supported dissenting views. A selection of them are summarised in the concluding paragraph.


=='''The Main Macroeconomic Theories'''==
=='''The Main Macroeconomic Theories'''==
===The circular flow of income===
===The circular flow of income===
The simplest  theoretical model of a national  economy is  a  system consisting of all of the country’s firms on the one hand, and  all of its  households on the other. National income in such a system is the total value of the firms’ output, which must be the same as the amount of  money reaching the households in the form of wages interest and dividends (it has nowhere else to go).  That  money is  then either saved, or spent on the firms’ products. The money reaching the firms consists of that spent by consumers and that invested  (ie spent on the purchase of capital equipment from some of  the firms).  National income is thus both household spending  plus savings and household spending plus investment.  It follows, as a matter of arithmetic, that in such a system, savings must match investment.  But in the economy as we know it,  savings plans and investment plans are mostly made independently by different people.  If the model is to represent what happens in such an economy, it must contain a mechanism by which planned investment is brought into line with planned savings  
The simplest  theoretical model of a national  economy is  a  system consisting of all of the country’s firms on the one hand, and  all of its  households on the other <ref> For a diagrammatic representation of the model, see the tutorials subpage</ref>. National income <ref> For a definition of National income, see the article on [[Gross Domestic Product]]</ref> in such a system is the total value of the firms’ output, which must be the same as the amount of  money reaching the households in the form of wages interest and dividends (it has nowhere else to go).  That  money is  then either saved, or spent on the firms’ products. The money reaching the firms consists of that spent by consumers and that invested  (ie spent on the purchase of capital equipment by some of  the firms).  National income is thus both household spending  plus savings and household spending plus investment.  It follows, as a matter of arithmetic, that in such a system, savings must match investment.  But in the economy as we know it,  savings plans and investment plans are mostly made independently by different people.  If the model is to represent what happens in such an economy, it must contain a mechanism by which planned investment is brought into line with planned savings.
 


===The classical model===
===The classical model===
Classical theory  applies  the market mechanism (which is described in the article on [[microeconomics]]) both  to the problem of reconciling savings and investment plans, and to the operation of the labour market. It envisages the economy as a set of inter-linked markets with supply in one market determining demand in others in a manner which could be represented as a vast set of simultaneous equations. It embodies the concept of ''[[general equilibrium]]'' in which an imaginary auctioneer organises trading at prices which keep demand constantly in supply in all markets. It assumes in particular that in the market for savings, an excess of planned saving over planned investment would result in a reduction in the interest rate sufficient to bring the plans into line – and vice versa.  In the market for labour, it assumes that if the planned demand for labour fell below the level required for full employment, wages would fall to a level at which full employment would be restored.  The economy is thus taken to have a self-righting capacity as regards both output and employment.
Classical theory  applies  the [[market (economics)|market]] mechanism (which is described in the article on [[microeconomics]]) both  to the problem of reconciling savings and investment plans, and to the operation of the labour market. It envisages the economy as a set of inter-linked markets with supply in one market determining demand in others in a manner which could be represented as a vast set of simultaneous equations. It embodies the concept of "general equilibrium" in which an imaginary auctioneer organises trading at prices which reconcile [[supply and demand]] in all markets. It assumes in particular that in the market for savings, an excess of planned saving over planned investment would result in a reduction in the interest rate sufficient to bring the plans into line – and vice versa.  In the market for labour, it assumes that if the planned demand for labour fell below the level required for full employment, wages would fall to a level at which full [[employment]] would be restored.  The economy is thus taken to have a self-righting capacity as regards both output and employment.


===The Keynesian model===
===[[Keynesian theory]]===
In the Keynesian model,  planned savings are determined mainly by the level of income of the households. The adjustment mechanism by which a rise in planned saving  would be  brought into line with planned investment would be  a fall in firms’ output -  resulting in a sufficient fall in household income to reduce planned savings to  equality with planned investment. And if the fall in output brought about  a reduction in planned investment, there would be a further output reduction.  The economy could settle into a stable condition in which output was below productive capacity. In the Keynesian model, moreover, the labour market does not have a self-righting capacity either,  because wages are assumed to be “sticky downwards”,  so the output fall would be accompanied by a rise in unemployment.
According to  [[Keynesian theory]],  planned savings are determined mainly by the level of income of the households. The adjustment mechanism by which a rise in planned saving  would be  brought into line with planned investment would be  a fall in firms’ output -  resulting in a sufficient fall in household income to reduce planned savings to  equality with planned investment. And if the fall in output brought about  a reduction in planned investment, there would be a further output reduction.  The economy could settle into a stable condition in which output was below productive capacity. In the Keynesian model, moreover, the labour market does not have a self-righting capacity either,  because wages are assumed to be “sticky downwards”,  so the output fall would be accompanied by a rise in unemployment. The basic model was extended by John Hicks to create a model of the equilibrium level of demand in both product and monetary markets - known as the [[IS/LM model]].


===Monetarism===
===Monetarism===
In its simplest form, monetarism seems to offer an easily understood explanation of inflation and a straightforward prescription for its cure. It seems obvious that if pound notes were dropped from a helicopter to the extent necessary to double the amount in circulation,  then prices  would double. It is a small step to the conclusion that inflation is caused by increases in the money supply , and an obvious further step to prescribe control of the money supply as the cause for inflation. Those conclusions are not in fact obvious because they depend upon the assumption that people would spend the additional money on goods. That need not be the case. The assumption of the Keynesian model is that they would spend it all on interest-bearing financial assets, and on that assumption there would be no tendency to bid up prices in the goods marketAll depends upon which assumption is nearer the truth. Monetary economics is mainly about the answer to that question. An examination of the statistics revealed a strong association  between money supply and the monetary value of national income in the United States and in Britain  <ref> C A E Goodhart ''Monetary Theory and Practice'' Macmillan 1984 </ref> (with income  roughly constant in real terms, that implied that the main change had been in prices). For various reasons that conclusion turned out not to be decisive, however.  
[[Monetarism]] is a theory that explains  [[inflation]] as the inevitable consequence of an increase in the [[money supply]]. It is conventionally explained in terms of the "quantity theory of [[money]]" <ref>[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/money/quantity.htm Quantity  Theory of Money (CEPA)]</ref> which derives from the identity MV=PT, in which M is money stock, V the velocity with which money circulates, P the average price level and T the number of transactions. An implication of that equation is that if  V and T can be assumed constant,  an increase in the [[money supply]] (normally taken to be cash plus bank deposits) will produce a corresponding increase in the general level of pricesMonetarism is founded upon the contention that for practical purposes, V and T can be assumed constant. Its validity  thus  depends upon the empirical confirmation of that assumption. An analysis of United States statistics <ref> Friedman and Meiselman The relative stability of monetary velocity and the Investment Multiplier in the United States 1897-1958 in ''Stabilisation Policies, CMC Research Papers'' p165 Prentice-Hall 1964</ref>, indicated that price increases had, in fact, followed money supply increases, but with time-lags that were long and variable.  Critics argued that this was not conclusive proof,  and  further statistical tests <ref>
[http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/monetarism/monetarcont.htm The development of monetarism (CEPA)]</ref>  were attempted to test it against the Keynesian theory that increases in the money supply would not affect the prices of goods because they would be spent on financial assets. The results did not give conclusive support to that alternative explanation, nor to the contention that it could safely be ignored.


=='''Qualifications and Extensions'''==
=='''Qualifications and Extensions'''==
===Expectations===
===Expectations===
None of the above theories makes allowance for the fact that people learn from experience.  The fact that they do has a bearing upon economic activity, however.  The price that an investor pays for a security is determined by  expectations of future returns, based upon the  experience of past performance. But it is hard to say how widely such behaviour applies. The assumption that people generally fail to learn from experience and make persistent forecasting errors is clearly unsatisfactory,  but the opposite assumption is also difficult to believe. The ''Rational Expectations Hypothesis''  <ref> GK Shaw  ''Rational Expectations'',  Wheatsheaf  Books, Harvester Press 1984 </ref> postulates that, in forming their expectations, people make use of all of the relevant information; and that, although they may make random errors, their forecasts are not systematically biased. While not claiming it to be literally true, economists of the ''New Classical school'' claim that it offers a better hypothesis concerning the working of the economy than the available alternatives. Experience has shown that expectations do in fact have a significant influence upon some aspects of economic behaviour. In particular, it has been found that the inflation rate at any given time is influenced by expectations of future inflation - a fact that has implications for the conduct of monetary policy.
None of the above theories makes allowance for the fact that people learn from experience.  The fact that they do has a bearing upon economic activity, however.  The price that an investor pays for a security is determined by  expectations of future returns, based upon the  experience of past performance. But it is hard to say how widely such behaviour applies. The assumption that people generally fail to learn from experience and make persistent forecasting errors is clearly unsatisfactory,  but the opposite assumption is also difficult to believe. The ''[[Rational Expectations Hypothesis]]''  <ref> GK Shaw  ''Rational Expectations'',  Wheatsheaf  Books, Harvester Press 1984 </ref> postulates that, in forming their expectations, people make use of all of the relevant information; and that, although they may make random errors, their forecasts are not systematically biased. While not claiming it to be literally true, economists of the ''New Classical school'' claim that it offers a better hypothesis concerning the working of the economy than the available alternatives. Experience has shown that expectations do in fact have a significant influence upon some aspects of economic behaviour. In particular, it has been found that the inflation rate at any given time is influenced by expectations of future inflation - a fact that has implications for the conduct of [[monetary policy]].


===The natural rate of unemployment===
===The natural rate of unemployment===
The concept of expectations is conceptually  relevant to the level of unemployment.  A relationship between wage increases and unemployment was discovered in the late 1950s that was  known as the ''Phillips Curve'' <ref> A W H Phillips "The Relation Between Unemployment and the Rate of Change of Money Wages in the UK 1861-1951 ''Economica'' November 1958.</ref>  But subsequent experience suggested the possibility of  an association between the unemployment rate and both the inflation rate and the expected inflation rate -  referred to as the ''expectations augmented Phillips curve'' <ref>  See  K A Christal ''Controversies in British Macroeconomics''  George Allen and Unwin 1958 for a diagrammatic exposition  </ref>. As a point of reference, the unemployment rate at which the expected  inflation rate is the same as the actual inflation rate was termed ''The Non-Accelerating Inflation Rate of unemployment'' (NAIRU) or simply the natural rate of unemployment.  The idea was that if unemployment were to  rise,  the expected inflation rate and the actual inflation rate would both fall, and that in the long term unemployment would fall back to its natural rate as expected inflation came back into line with actual inflation.
The concept of expectations is conceptually  relevant to the level of [[unemployment]].  A relationship between wage increases and unemployment was discovered in the late 1950s that was  known as the ''[[Phillips Curve]]'' <ref> A W H Phillips "The Relation Between Unemployment and the Rate of Change of Money Wages in the UK 1861-1951 ''Economica'' November 1958.</ref>  But subsequent experience suggested the possibility of  an association between the unemployment rate and both the inflation rate and the expected inflation rate -  referred to as the ''expectations augmented Phillips curve'' <ref>[http://nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economics/laureates/1976/friedman-lecture.pdf Milton Friedman: ''Inflation and Unemployment'' Nobel Memorial Lecture 1976]</ref> <ref>  See  K A Christal ''Controversies in British Macroeconomics''  George Allen and Unwin 1958 for a diagrammatic exposition  </ref>. As a point of reference, the unemployment rate at which the expected  inflation rate is the same as the actual inflation rate was termed ''The Non-Accelerating Inflation Rate of unemployment'' (NAIRU).  The idea was that if unemployment were to  rise,  the expected inflation rate and the actual inflation rate would both fall, and that in the long term unemployment would fall back to its natural rate as expected inflation came back into line with actual inflation.


===The output gap===
===The output gap===
The difference between the actual and the natural  rate of unemployment  is  related to the difference between actual and potential output according to ''Okun’s Law'' <ref> Martin Prachowny    "Okun's Law: Theoretical Foundations and Revised Estimates". ''The Review of Economics and Statistics,'' Vol. 75, No. 2. (May, 1993), pp. 331-336 </ref>.  And the difference between actual and potential output, known as ''the output gap'', is  a factor affecting inflation.  That  is the basis of the ''Taylor Rule'' referred to below, which can be regarded as a version of the Phillips curve in which it is the output gap rather than the unemployment rate that determines  the inflation rate.
The difference between the actual and the [[natural  rate of unemployment]] is  related to the difference between actual and potential output according to [[Okun's law]] <ref> Martin Prachowny    "Okun's Law: Theoretical Foundations and Revised Estimates". ''The Review of Economics and Statistics,'' Vol. 75, No. 2. (May, 1993), pp. 331-336 </ref>, and the monetarist alternative attributed to [[Milton Friedman]]<ref>[http://world-economics-journal.com Tim Congdon: "Two Concepts of the Output Gap", ''World Economics vol 9 n'Jan-Mar 2008]</ref>.  And the difference between actual and potential output, known as the [[output gap]], is  a factor affecting inflation.  That  is the basis of the [[Monetary policy/Addendum#The Taylor rule|Taylor rule]] which can be regarded as a version of the [[Phillips curve]] in which it is the output gap rather than the unemployment rate that determines  the inflation rate. Estimates of the size of the output gap can be subject to a significant degree of uncertainty<ref>[http://budgetresponsibility.independent.gov.uk/wordpress/docs/briefing%20paper%20No2%20FINAL.pdf Estimating the output gap. UK Office of Budget Responsibility, April 2011]</ref><ref>[http://ftalphaville.ft.com/2012/10/04/1191411/why-the-uk-output-gap-could-be-a-chasm/ Izabella Kaminska, ''Why the UK output gap could be a chasm'', FT Alphaville,  Oct 4 2012]</ref>


===Disequilibrium===
===Disequilibrium===
When the unrealistic assumptions of general equilibrium theory are replaced by a more realistic account of the working of the  economy, other explanations of unemployment emerge.  In practice many of the adjustments toward an equilibrium in which between supply matches  demand  are incomplete at any particular point in time; and even as some adjustments approach completion, others are just starting.  Thus the real economy is always to some extent  in a state of disequilibrium, with shortages and surpluses always to be found somewhere or another. Unemployment could arise from the slowness  or absence of price responses in the market for goods, as well as in the labour market. Although not envisaged by the classical economists, that possibility has been termed ''classical unemployment'' to distinguish it from Keynesian demand-deficient unemployment.  Economic analysis of that possibility is termed ''Disequilibrium Macroeconomics'' <ref> see R J Barro and H Grossman ''Money, Employment and Inflation''  Cambridge University Press 1976 </ref>. The possibility of reducing the extent of disequilibrium in the economy is discussed below under the heading of ''The Supply Side''.
When the unrealistic assumptions of general equilibrium theory are replaced by a more realistic account of the working of the  economy, other explanations of unemployment emerge.  In practice many of the adjustments toward an equilibrium in which between supply matches  demand  are incomplete at any particular point in time; and even as some adjustments approach completion, others are just starting.  Thus the real economy is always to some extent  in a state of disequilibrium, with shortages and surpluses always to be found somewhere or another. Unemployment could arise from the slowness  or absence of price responses in the market for goods, as well as in the labour market. Although not envisaged by the classical economists, that possibility has been termed ''classical unemployment'' to distinguish it from Keynesian demand-deficient unemployment.  Economic analysis of that possibility is termed ''disequilibrium macroeconomics'' <ref> see R J Barro and H Grossman ''Money, Employment and Inflation''  Cambridge University Press 1976 </ref>.


===Imports and exports===
===Imports and exports===
The circular flow of income construction used in the basic Keynesian theory  takes no account of  imports and exports. A simplified version of the  conventional explanation of what happens when they are taken into account is that an increase in domestic demand leads to an increase in imports, and the resultant imbalance between imports and exports is eventually corrected by a fall in the exchange rate.  (That mechanism is explained more fully in the article on [[International Trade]]).  An alternative explanation  is provided by the ''monetary approach to the balance of payments''  <ref> H G Johnson ''International Trade and Economic Growth'' chapter 6 George Allen and Unwin 1958 </ref>. which treats the exchange rate as the relative price of  moneys in circulation in the two countries in question. Payments for exports increase the domestic money supply and payments for imports reduce it.  That system is self–balancing because an increase in imports  causes a fall in the money supply which causes a fall  in domestic activity which causes  imports to fall. According to that explanation, it is only if  the domestic money supply is increased that the exchange rate will fall.
The circular flow of income construction used in the basic Keynesian theory  takes no account of  imports and exports. A simplified version of the  conventional explanation of what happens when they are taken into account is that an increase in domestic demand leads to an increase in imports, and the resultant deficit in the [[balance of payments]] is eventually corrected by a fall in the exchange rate. The determination of domestic equilibrium in an open economy is the subject of the  [[Mundell-Fleming model]] (see also the article on [[International Economics]]).  An alternative explanation  is provided by the ''monetary approach to the balance of payments''  <ref> H G Johnson ''International Trade and Economic Growth'' chapter 6 George Allen and Unwin 1958 </ref>. which treats the exchange rate as the relative price of  moneys in circulation in the two countries in question. Payments for exports increase the domestic money supply and payments for imports reduce it.  That system is self–balancing because an increase in imports  causes a fall in the money supply which causes a fall  in domestic activity which causes  imports to fall. According to that explanation, it is only if  the domestic money supply is increased that the exchange rate will fall.


===The money supply===
===The money supply===
Evidence that emerged some years after the initial formulation of monetarism established its validity, together with some serious limitations upon its usefulness. It revealed a significant long-term association between the money supply and inflation. But, in addition to the variable time-lags in the relation that had been recognised in the original theories, that association exhibited a great deal of short-term instability. Nevertheless, large increases in the money supply are now  generally  recognised to give a rough indication of the probability of forthcoming inflation. But, as noted below, the belief of early monetarists that inflation could be controlled in the short term by control of the money supply, turned out to be mistaken<ref> Nick Gardner ''Decade of Discontent'' pp 205-207 Basil Blackwell 1987 </ref>
Evidence that emerged some years after the initial formulation of [[monetarism]] revealed a significant long-term association between the [[money supply]] and [[inflation]] with, however, a great deal of short-term instability. Attempts in the early 1980 to implement the monetarist prescription by the use of money supply targets ran into serious difficulties. In Britain, the Government adopted a four-year  programme of progressively diminishing targets for money supply growth termed the ''Medium Term Financial Strategy'' but found itself so far unable to implement them that the growth in the money supply was no lower at the end of the period than at the beginning <ref> Nick Gardner ''Decade of Discontent'' pp 205-207 Basil Blackwell 1987 </ref>. Money supply targets had also been introduced in the United States and other western countries but had not appeared to have the intended effect. By 1985 they had generally been abandoned in favour of inflation-targeting procedures - in which, however,  money supply growth is usually one of the factors that are taken into account.
.  
 


=='''Management of the Economy'''==
=='''Management of the Economy'''==
===Tackling unemployment===
===Tackling unemployment===
The classical economists believed  that nothing could be done to reduce unemployment except by reducing market rigidities by what are now known as [[supply-side measures]]. Keynesians believed that  any tendency for demand to fall below the level necessary for full employment could be corrected by increased public expenditure or reduced taxation. That  would be partly effected without  specific government action by the operation of the economy’s ''built in stabilisers''. (By that was meant the tendency for tax payments to fall as the level of activity falls, and vice-versa.) Monetary economists recommended using a combination of  built-in stabilisers and supply-side measures. <ref> Milton Friedman A Monetary  and Fiscal Framework  for Economic Stability” in ''Essays in Positive Economics''  Phoenix Books 1966 </ref>. Each of those recommendations was followed to some extent in the course of the twentieth century, with results that were often considered to be unsatisfactory.  
The classical economists believed  that nothing could be done to reduce unemployment except by reducing market rigidities. [[Keynesians]] believe that  any tendency for demand to fall below the level necessary for full employment can be corrected by increased [[public expenditure]] or reduced [[taxation]]. That  would be partly effected without  specific government action by the operation of the economy’s [[automatic stabilisers]][[monetarism|Monetarists]] recommend using a combination of  automatic stabilisers and [[supply-side measures]]. <ref> Milton Friedman "A Monetary  and Fiscal Framework  for Economic Stability" in ''Essays in Positive Economics''  Phoenix Books 1966 </ref>. However, a [[fiscal stimulus]] can quickly boost spending power, whereas [[monetary policy]] acts with  long and  uncertain lags.  Discretionary fiscal policy has often been used to regulate developed economies but, because of legislative delays it has sometimes had a destabilising effect because the stimulus arrived when activity was recovering. A study by economists at the [[International Monetary Fund]] has shown that a fiscal stimulus package equivalent to 1 percent of country's [[Gross Domestic Product|GDP]] is associated on average with GDP increases of about 0.1 to 0.2 percent. In advanced economies, the longer-term effects are also positive and even possibly higher. But the longer-term effects are typically negative in emerging economies.
<ref>[http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2008/02/pdf/c5.pdf ''Fiscal Policy as a Countercyclical  Tool'', IMF World Economic Outlook, Chapter 5,  October 2008]</ref>.


===Controlling inflation===
===Controlling inflation===
 
In the 1970s Keynesian economists considered inflation to be mainly the consequence of existing wage bargaining systems, and recommended incomes policies as a means of control. Incomes policies  were tried in the USA and in Britain, but never had more than a brief transitory effect on inflation. On the contrary, their ineffectiveness sometimes generated adverse inflationary expectations that caused people to behave in ways that gave impetus to the growth of inflation. As already noted, attempts to control inflation by setting  money supply targets were also unsuccessful. Current practice, described below, uses published inflation rate targets and attempts to meet them using the Central Banks' power to control interest rates.
In the 1970s Keynesian economists considered inflation to be mainly the consequence of existing wage bargaining systems, and recommended incomes policies as a means of control. Incomes policies  were tried in the USA and in Britain, but never had more than a brief transitory effect on inflation. Their ineffectiveness generated adverse inflationary expectations that caused poeple to behave in ways that gave impetus to the growth of inflation. Central to the Monetarist thesis was the recommendation that inflation should be controlled by setting and meeting challenging money supply targets. It was intended that the setting of targets would dampen inflationary expectations to the point that reductions in money supply would not cause a significant increase in unemployment. That course of action was adopted in the United States and in Britain. In Britain,in particular, technical difficulties frustrated the attempt to control the money supply, and the changes in the inflation rate that followed appeared to be unrelated to the money supply.  Most economists attribute the reduction in the inflation rate that followed, to that policy's adverse effect upon output and the employment rate. Current practice, described below, uses published inflation rate targets and attempts to meet them using the Central Banks' power to control interest rates.  


===Current monetary policy===
===Current monetary policy===
Under normal circumstances, [[monetary policy]] is nowadays targeted directly upon the [[inflation]] rate and aims to maintain it within predetermined limits. It operates by use of the [[central bank]]s power to control [[interest rate]]s <ref> [http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/other/monetary/bean070413.pdf Charles Bean ''Is There a Consensus in Monetary Policy?'']</ref>.).  Briefly, an increase in interest rates discourages borrowing and encourages savings.  Because borrowers spend more than savers, it discourages consumer spending, and higher mortgage payments reinforce its effect by leaving householders with less to spend. Since it takes about a year for interest rate changes  to affect output and two years to affect inflation, policy action depends upon judgements  of forthcoming inflation. The authorities make use of [[economic forecasting models]] to assist those judgements, but they usually take account also of a range of factors including inflationary expectations (as indicated by the differences between the prices of fixed-interest and index-linked bonds) and the state of the housing  market. Regulatory action depends mainly upon empirical data concerning the relation between the inflation rate and the ''output gap'' such as is embodied in the ''Taylor Rule''<ref>John B Taylor "Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice", in  ''Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy'' no 39 1993 [http://www.stanford.edu/~johntayl/Papers/Discretion.PDF] </ref><ref>[http://www.stanford.edu/~johntayl/PolRulLink.htm Stanford University Monetary Policy Rule Homepage]</ref>.


Monetary policy in most countries is nowadays targeted directly upon the inflation rate and aims to maintain it within predetermined limits. It operates by use of the central bank's power to control interest rates (as explained by the Bank of England <ref>[http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/monetarypolicy/how.htm Bank of England Note: ''How monetary policy works'']</ref>).  Briefly, an increase in interest rates discourages borrowing and encourages savings.  Because borrowers spend more than savers it discourages consumer spending, and higher mortgage payments reinforce its effect by leaving householders with less to spend. Since it takes about a year for interest rate changes  to affect output and two years to affect inflation, policy action depends upon judgements  of forthcoming inflation. The authorities make use of [[economic models]] to assist those judgements, but they usually take account also of a range of factors including inflationary expectations (as indicated by the differences between the prices of fixed-interest and index-linked bonds) and the state of the housing.  market. Regulatory action depends mainly upon empirical data concerning the relation between the inflation rate and the output gap such as is embodied in the ''Taylor Rule''<ref>John B Taylor "Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice", in  ''Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy'' no 39 1993 </ref>.
Under exceptional circumstances such as a severe [[recession]], a [[credit crunch]] or an impending [[deflation]], [[monetary policy]] may be used to create an increase in the [[money supply]] by substantial reductions in interest rates, and - if that action reduces its effectiveness - by the creation of money by a technique known as [[quantitative easing]]
(For a straightforward account of the development of current monetary policy see the account by Charles Bean <ref> [http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/other/monetary/bean070413.pdf Charles Bean ''Is There a Consensus in Monetary Policy?'']</ref>.)


=='''Economic Policy'''==
=='''Economic Policy'''==
===Policy aims===
===Policy aims===
Macroeconomics is concerned with the policy aim of achieving stability of economic activity and of the price level, and with the policy aim of achieving growth of the country's economic well-being. According to the current ([[neoclassical economics]]) consensus, both aims are well served by the effective working of [[competition]] in markets for goods and services. That is because competitive markets have the flexibility to respond to external shocks to the economy and because they promote economic efficiency and facilitate growth by directing economic resources into activities that improve economic welfare. Consequently, many of the policy actions considered are concerned either with the removal of obstacles to market competition, or with the promotion of [[economic efficiency]] in activities that cannot normally be traded (such as defence and public health). The policy instruments by which those aims can be pursued fall into the three categories of public expenditure, taxation and regulation.
[[Macroeconomic policy]] is concerned with the policy aim of achieving stability of economic activity and of the price level, and with the policy aim of achieving growth of the country's economic well-being. The policy instruments by which those aims can be pursued fall into the three categories of public expenditure, taxation and regulation.


===Public expenditure===
===Public expenditure===
Spending by local and central government is made up of transfer payments (such as social security payments), the provision of goods and services, and subsidies to private sector providers of goods and services. Of particular economic significance are [[public goods]] such as the infrastructure, which the market cannot supply because they cannot be bought and sold by individuals. Equally significant are goods that have public benefits which would otherwise be underprovided by the market. An example in the latter category is industrial research which, without government subsidies, would be underprovided because  some of its benefits are often  copied and thus lost to its providers. Another example is training by employers, which would be underprovided because of the prospect that some employees will leave, taking with them the skills that they have learned. According to [[endogenous growth theory]] those factors may be expected to have a determining effect on economic growth rates. Then there are activities such as education and medical care that are directed at the welfare of their clients but which have spin-off effects upon the community in terms of the benefits of living among healthy, well-educated people. Those ''externalities'' are held to  justify some degree of subsidy, particularly as they may be expected to  contribute to growth prospects. In principle, the criterion for each item of  public investment is the satisfaction of a [[cost/benefit analysis]] criterion, with the amount of investment determined by the requirement that its marginal benefit should be equal to its marginal cost; and public investment that fails that test may be expected to reduce economic efficiency, as may failure to make investments that pass it. In practice, however, the necessary information may be uncertain or unavailable. In practice, also, the total amount of government expenditure may be limited by a budgetary constraint. If public expenditure exceeds the revenue from taxation, the resulting budget deficit has to be financed by borrowing. As noted in the  above paragraph on current stabilisation policies, the tendency for deficits to increase during a recession in demand provides a contribution to the maintenance of stability. The resulting ''cyclical deficit'' may be expected to be balanced by a budgetary surplus during the cycle's recovery phase, leaving the total of the  national debt unchanged. However, it is generally feared that a non-cyclical or ''structural deficit'' will have adverse long-term consequences, "crowding-out" private sector investment <ref> [http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/44/45/35554787.pdf  OECD Economic Studies No. 4, Spring 1985 - ''Budget Deficits and Crowding-out''] </ref> , increasing taxation, and possibly raising the inflation rate. Although the evidence for those fears is somewhat uncertain, there is a widespread consensus that structural deficits should be limited and  preferably avoided. (In Britain the then Chancellor embodied that intention in what came to be known as the [[budgetary golden rule]]).
[[Public expenditure]] by local and central government is made up of transfer payments (such as social security payments), the provision of goods and services, and subsidies to private sector providers of goods and services. Of particular economic significance are [[public goods]] such as the infrastructure, which the market cannot supply because they cannot be bought and sold by individuals. Equally significant are goods that have public benefits which would otherwise be under-provided by the market. An example in the latter category is industrial research which, without government subsidies, would be underprovided because  some of its benefits are often  copied and thus lost to its providers. Another example is training by employers, which would be under-provided because of the prospect that some employees will leave, taking with them the skills that they have learned. According to [[endogenous growth]] theory those factors may be expected to have a determining effect on economic growth rates. Then there are activities such as education and medical care that are directed at the welfare of their clients but which have spin-off effects upon the community in terms of the benefits of living among healthy, well-educated people. Those [[externalities]] are held to  justify some degree of subsidy, particularly as they may be expected to  contribute to growth prospects. In principle, the criterion for each item of  public investment is the satisfaction of a [[cost/benefit analysis]] criterion, with the amount of investment determined by the requirement that its marginal benefit should be equal to its marginal cost; and public investment that fails that test may be expected to reduce economic efficiency, as may failure to make investments that pass it. In practice, however, the necessary information may be uncertain or unavailable. In practice, also, the total amount of government expenditure may be limited by a budgetary constraint. If public expenditure exceeds the revenue from taxation, the resulting [[budget deficit]] has to be financed by borrowing. As noted in the  above paragraph on current stabilisation policies, the tendency for deficits to increase during a recession in demand provides a contribution to the maintenance of stability. The resulting ''cyclical deficit'' may be expected to be balanced by a budgetary surplus during the cycle's recovery phase, leaving the total of the  national debt unchanged. However, it is generally feared that a non-cyclical or ''structural deficit'' will have adverse long-term consequences, "crowding-out" private sector investment <ref> [http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/44/45/35554787.pdf  OECD Economic Studies No. 4, Spring 1985 - ''Budget Deficits and Crowding-out''] </ref> , increasing taxation, and possibly raising the inflation rate. Although the evidence for those fears is somewhat uncertain, there is a widespread consensus that structural budget deficits should be limited and  preferably avoided.


==Taxation==
===Taxation===
There is evidence to suggest that taxation can reduce economic output and growth in a number of different ways. Redistributive taxes  can reduce private savings and investment because the  rich save more than the poor.  Income tax and social security contributions can reduce employment and output because the difference that they create  between what employers pay and what employees receive, reduces work incentives. Other taxes can distort supply and demand relationships in other markets to the detriment of economic efficiency.  According to an OECD working paper <ref> [http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/33/25/1863834.pdf Leibfritz et al, OECD Working Paper No. 176 1997 ''Taxation and Economic Performance''] </ref>, however, a review of published evidence indicates that  “the effects of taxes on economic performance are ambiguous in some areas and unsettled and controversial in others” The only unequivocal policy conclusion that emerges from the evidence is that economic performance is best served by  taxes that do not distort incentives such as a poll tax or a tax on land values. (Exceptions may arise, however, when the incentives promoted are used as an alternative to the economically positive regulations referred to in the next paragraph.)
There is evidence to suggest that [[taxation]] can reduce economic output and growth in a number of different ways. Redistributive taxes  can reduce private savings and investment because the  rich save more than the poor.  Income tax and social security contributions can reduce employment and output because the difference that they create  between what employers pay and what employees receive, reduces work incentives. Other taxes can distort [[supply and demand]] relationships in other markets to the detriment of economic efficiency.  According to an OECD working paper <ref> [http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/33/25/1863834.pdf Leibfritz et al, OECD Working Paper No. 176 1997 ''Taxation and Economic Performance''] </ref>, however, a review of published evidence indicates that  “the effects of taxes on economic performance are ambiguous in some areas and unsettled and controversial in others” The only unequivocal policy conclusion that emerges from the evidence is that economic performance is best served by  taxes that do not distort incentives, such as a poll tax or a tax on land values.


==Regulation==
===Regulation===
In most countries, regulatory policy has significant positive and negative effects upon economic efficiency, output and growth. On the positive side is the basic framework of laws, regulations and codes of practice without which economic activity on the modern scale would not be possible. Without an effective system of law-enforcement and an accepted way of settling disputes,for example, much activity would be diverted from production and exchange into defence against violence. Also on the positive side – or potentially so – are measures to promote competition, either by removing barriers, as in the case of [[antitrust]] or [[competition policy]], or by providing consumers with information that they would otherwise lack, as in the case of product standards. In the case of ''natural monopolies'', and otherwise in absence of  effective competition, regulations can be used to limit the extent of anti-competitive  behaviour.  Growth may also  be facilitated by systems of [[patent law]] that provide  incentives to  innovation that might otherwise be lacking.  Offsetting the benefits in every case are the costs to companies and individuals of complying with the regulations. On the negative side as far as macroeconomic considerations are concerned, are the many regulations that yield no economic benefit, and those whose costs exceed their benefits. Among them are regulations that prohibit innovation on the grounds of the mere possibility of harm – as advocated in the more extreme interpretations of [[the precautionary principle]] – and safety  regulations that are based upon mistaken estimates of the expected (probability-weighted) negative value of the events against which they guard<ref>Aaron Wildavsky  ''Searching for Safety''  Transaction Publishers , 1988</ref> .
In most countries, regulatory policy has significant positive and negative effects upon economic efficiency, output and growth. On the positive side is the basic framework of laws, regulations and codes of practice without which economic activity on the modern scale would not be possible. Without an effective system of law-enforcement and an accepted way of settling disputes,for example, much activity would be diverted from production and exchange into defence against violence. Also on the positive side are measures to promote competition, either by removing barriers, as in the case of [[antitrust]] or [[competition policy]], or by providing consumers with information that they would otherwise lack, as in the case of product standards.   Growth may also  be facilitated by systems of [[patent law]] that provide  incentives to  innovation that might otherwise be lacking.  Offsetting the benefits in every case are the costs to companies and individuals of complying with the regulations. On the negative side as far as macroeconomic considerations are concerned, are regulations that yield no economic benefit, and those whose costs exceed their benefits. Among them are regulations that prohibit innovation on the grounds of the mere possibility of harm – as advocated in the more extreme interpretations of the [[precautionary principle]] – and safety  regulations that are based upon mistaken estimates of the  negative value of the events against which they guard<ref>Aaron Wildavsky  ''Searching for Safety''  Transaction Publishers , 1988</ref> .


==Dissenting views==
==Dissenting views==
Among dissenting views are those of:
*economists of the [[Austrian School]] who consider the economy to be too complex to justify the use  of macroeconomic aggregates, and who use logical deductions from axioms rather than induction from economic statistics;
*[[sustainability]] advocates who favour restricting or halting economic growth in order to preserve resources for the use of future generations;


=='''References'''==
=='''References'''==
<references/>
{{reflist}}[[Category:Suggestion Bot Tag]]
[[Category:CZ Live]]
[[Category:Economics Workgroup]]

Latest revision as of 16:00, 14 September 2024

This article is developed but not approved.
Main Article
Discussion
Related Articles  [?]
Bibliography  [?]
External Links  [?]
Citable Version  [?]
Tutorials [?]
 
This editable, developed Main Article is subject to a disclaimer.

Macroeconomics is the study of the national economy viewed as a single interactive system. It is concerned, not with individual transactions, but with economy-wide aggregates, including national income, the rate of inflation and the unemployment rate. At the theoretical level it seeks to explain how national income grows, how it fluctuates and what then happens to prices and unemployment. At the positive level it tests competing theories against the evidence provided by economic statistics, and it estimates the numerical relationships required to construct forecasting models. At the application level it considers what policies would serve to promote economic stability and growth and full employment.

Since a national economy is too complex to analyse for those purposes, macroeconomics uses simplified versions which ignore those components that are thought to have relatively little influence upon the question under consideration. The initial procedure postulates the way that the components of the system interact and deduces from those postulated relationships, how the system as a whole may be expected to behave. That deductive process is normally followed by the use of evidence and inductive reasoning to test, either the relationships themselves, or the deduced behaviour of the system.

This article summarises the main concepts and theories of macroeconomics without attempting to attribute them to those responsible; and some of its later paragraphs are confined to what is believed to be the consensus view among professional economists. Readers seeking an account of how, and by whom, those and other theories were developed should consult the article on the history of economic thought.

The Main Macroeconomic Theories

The circular flow of income

The simplest theoretical model of a national economy is a system consisting of all of the country’s firms on the one hand, and all of its households on the other [1]. National income [2] in such a system is the total value of the firms’ output, which must be the same as the amount of money reaching the households in the form of wages interest and dividends (it has nowhere else to go). That money is then either saved, or spent on the firms’ products. The money reaching the firms consists of that spent by consumers and that invested (ie spent on the purchase of capital equipment by some of the firms). National income is thus both household spending plus savings and household spending plus investment. It follows, as a matter of arithmetic, that in such a system, savings must match investment. But in the economy as we know it, savings plans and investment plans are mostly made independently by different people. If the model is to represent what happens in such an economy, it must contain a mechanism by which planned investment is brought into line with planned savings.

The classical model

Classical theory applies the market mechanism (which is described in the article on microeconomics) both to the problem of reconciling savings and investment plans, and to the operation of the labour market. It envisages the economy as a set of inter-linked markets with supply in one market determining demand in others in a manner which could be represented as a vast set of simultaneous equations. It embodies the concept of "general equilibrium" in which an imaginary auctioneer organises trading at prices which reconcile supply and demand in all markets. It assumes in particular that in the market for savings, an excess of planned saving over planned investment would result in a reduction in the interest rate sufficient to bring the plans into line – and vice versa. In the market for labour, it assumes that if the planned demand for labour fell below the level required for full employment, wages would fall to a level at which full employment would be restored. The economy is thus taken to have a self-righting capacity as regards both output and employment.

Keynesian theory

According to Keynesian theory, planned savings are determined mainly by the level of income of the households. The adjustment mechanism by which a rise in planned saving would be brought into line with planned investment would be a fall in firms’ output - resulting in a sufficient fall in household income to reduce planned savings to equality with planned investment. And if the fall in output brought about a reduction in planned investment, there would be a further output reduction. The economy could settle into a stable condition in which output was below productive capacity. In the Keynesian model, moreover, the labour market does not have a self-righting capacity either, because wages are assumed to be “sticky downwards”, so the output fall would be accompanied by a rise in unemployment. The basic model was extended by John Hicks to create a model of the equilibrium level of demand in both product and monetary markets - known as the IS/LM model.

Monetarism

Monetarism is a theory that explains inflation as the inevitable consequence of an increase in the money supply. It is conventionally explained in terms of the "quantity theory of money" [3] which derives from the identity MV=PT, in which M is money stock, V the velocity with which money circulates, P the average price level and T the number of transactions. An implication of that equation is that if V and T can be assumed constant, an increase in the money supply (normally taken to be cash plus bank deposits) will produce a corresponding increase in the general level of prices. Monetarism is founded upon the contention that for practical purposes, V and T can be assumed constant. Its validity thus depends upon the empirical confirmation of that assumption. An analysis of United States statistics [4], indicated that price increases had, in fact, followed money supply increases, but with time-lags that were long and variable. Critics argued that this was not conclusive proof, and further statistical tests [5] were attempted to test it against the Keynesian theory that increases in the money supply would not affect the prices of goods because they would be spent on financial assets. The results did not give conclusive support to that alternative explanation, nor to the contention that it could safely be ignored.

Qualifications and Extensions

Expectations

None of the above theories makes allowance for the fact that people learn from experience. The fact that they do has a bearing upon economic activity, however. The price that an investor pays for a security is determined by expectations of future returns, based upon the experience of past performance. But it is hard to say how widely such behaviour applies. The assumption that people generally fail to learn from experience and make persistent forecasting errors is clearly unsatisfactory, but the opposite assumption is also difficult to believe. The Rational Expectations Hypothesis [6] postulates that, in forming their expectations, people make use of all of the relevant information; and that, although they may make random errors, their forecasts are not systematically biased. While not claiming it to be literally true, economists of the New Classical school claim that it offers a better hypothesis concerning the working of the economy than the available alternatives. Experience has shown that expectations do in fact have a significant influence upon some aspects of economic behaviour. In particular, it has been found that the inflation rate at any given time is influenced by expectations of future inflation - a fact that has implications for the conduct of monetary policy.

The natural rate of unemployment

The concept of expectations is conceptually relevant to the level of unemployment. A relationship between wage increases and unemployment was discovered in the late 1950s that was known as the Phillips Curve [7] But subsequent experience suggested the possibility of an association between the unemployment rate and both the inflation rate and the expected inflation rate - referred to as the expectations augmented Phillips curve [8] [9]. As a point of reference, the unemployment rate at which the expected inflation rate is the same as the actual inflation rate was termed The Non-Accelerating Inflation Rate of unemployment (NAIRU). The idea was that if unemployment were to rise, the expected inflation rate and the actual inflation rate would both fall, and that in the long term unemployment would fall back to its natural rate as expected inflation came back into line with actual inflation.

The output gap

The difference between the actual and the natural rate of unemployment is related to the difference between actual and potential output according to Okun's law [10], and the monetarist alternative attributed to Milton Friedman[11]. And the difference between actual and potential output, known as the output gap, is a factor affecting inflation. That is the basis of the Taylor rule which can be regarded as a version of the Phillips curve in which it is the output gap rather than the unemployment rate that determines the inflation rate. Estimates of the size of the output gap can be subject to a significant degree of uncertainty[12][13]

Disequilibrium

When the unrealistic assumptions of general equilibrium theory are replaced by a more realistic account of the working of the economy, other explanations of unemployment emerge. In practice many of the adjustments toward an equilibrium in which between supply matches demand are incomplete at any particular point in time; and even as some adjustments approach completion, others are just starting. Thus the real economy is always to some extent in a state of disequilibrium, with shortages and surpluses always to be found somewhere or another. Unemployment could arise from the slowness or absence of price responses in the market for goods, as well as in the labour market. Although not envisaged by the classical economists, that possibility has been termed classical unemployment to distinguish it from Keynesian demand-deficient unemployment. Economic analysis of that possibility is termed disequilibrium macroeconomics [14].

Imports and exports

The circular flow of income construction used in the basic Keynesian theory takes no account of imports and exports. A simplified version of the conventional explanation of what happens when they are taken into account is that an increase in domestic demand leads to an increase in imports, and the resultant deficit in the balance of payments is eventually corrected by a fall in the exchange rate. The determination of domestic equilibrium in an open economy is the subject of the Mundell-Fleming model (see also the article on International Economics). An alternative explanation is provided by the monetary approach to the balance of payments [15]. which treats the exchange rate as the relative price of moneys in circulation in the two countries in question. Payments for exports increase the domestic money supply and payments for imports reduce it. That system is self–balancing because an increase in imports causes a fall in the money supply which causes a fall in domestic activity which causes imports to fall. According to that explanation, it is only if the domestic money supply is increased that the exchange rate will fall.

The money supply

Evidence that emerged some years after the initial formulation of monetarism revealed a significant long-term association between the money supply and inflation with, however, a great deal of short-term instability. Attempts in the early 1980 to implement the monetarist prescription by the use of money supply targets ran into serious difficulties. In Britain, the Government adopted a four-year programme of progressively diminishing targets for money supply growth termed the Medium Term Financial Strategy but found itself so far unable to implement them that the growth in the money supply was no lower at the end of the period than at the beginning [16]. Money supply targets had also been introduced in the United States and other western countries but had not appeared to have the intended effect. By 1985 they had generally been abandoned in favour of inflation-targeting procedures - in which, however, money supply growth is usually one of the factors that are taken into account.

Management of the Economy

Tackling unemployment

The classical economists believed that nothing could be done to reduce unemployment except by reducing market rigidities. Keynesians believe that any tendency for demand to fall below the level necessary for full employment can be corrected by increased public expenditure or reduced taxation. That would be partly effected without specific government action by the operation of the economy’s automatic stabilisers. Monetarists recommend using a combination of automatic stabilisers and supply-side measures. [17]. However, a fiscal stimulus can quickly boost spending power, whereas monetary policy acts with long and uncertain lags. Discretionary fiscal policy has often been used to regulate developed economies but, because of legislative delays it has sometimes had a destabilising effect because the stimulus arrived when activity was recovering. A study by economists at the International Monetary Fund has shown that a fiscal stimulus package equivalent to 1 percent of country's GDP is associated on average with GDP increases of about 0.1 to 0.2 percent. In advanced economies, the longer-term effects are also positive and even possibly higher. But the longer-term effects are typically negative in emerging economies. [18].

Controlling inflation

In the 1970s Keynesian economists considered inflation to be mainly the consequence of existing wage bargaining systems, and recommended incomes policies as a means of control. Incomes policies were tried in the USA and in Britain, but never had more than a brief transitory effect on inflation. On the contrary, their ineffectiveness sometimes generated adverse inflationary expectations that caused people to behave in ways that gave impetus to the growth of inflation. As already noted, attempts to control inflation by setting money supply targets were also unsuccessful. Current practice, described below, uses published inflation rate targets and attempts to meet them using the Central Banks' power to control interest rates.

Current monetary policy

Under normal circumstances, monetary policy is nowadays targeted directly upon the inflation rate and aims to maintain it within predetermined limits. It operates by use of the central banks power to control interest rates [19].). Briefly, an increase in interest rates discourages borrowing and encourages savings. Because borrowers spend more than savers, it discourages consumer spending, and higher mortgage payments reinforce its effect by leaving householders with less to spend. Since it takes about a year for interest rate changes to affect output and two years to affect inflation, policy action depends upon judgements of forthcoming inflation. The authorities make use of economic forecasting models to assist those judgements, but they usually take account also of a range of factors including inflationary expectations (as indicated by the differences between the prices of fixed-interest and index-linked bonds) and the state of the housing market. Regulatory action depends mainly upon empirical data concerning the relation between the inflation rate and the output gap such as is embodied in the Taylor Rule[20][21].

Under exceptional circumstances such as a severe recession, a credit crunch or an impending deflation, monetary policy may be used to create an increase in the money supply by substantial reductions in interest rates, and - if that action reduces its effectiveness - by the creation of money by a technique known as quantitative easing

Economic Policy

Policy aims

Macroeconomic policy is concerned with the policy aim of achieving stability of economic activity and of the price level, and with the policy aim of achieving growth of the country's economic well-being. The policy instruments by which those aims can be pursued fall into the three categories of public expenditure, taxation and regulation.

Public expenditure

Public expenditure by local and central government is made up of transfer payments (such as social security payments), the provision of goods and services, and subsidies to private sector providers of goods and services. Of particular economic significance are public goods such as the infrastructure, which the market cannot supply because they cannot be bought and sold by individuals. Equally significant are goods that have public benefits which would otherwise be under-provided by the market. An example in the latter category is industrial research which, without government subsidies, would be underprovided because some of its benefits are often copied and thus lost to its providers. Another example is training by employers, which would be under-provided because of the prospect that some employees will leave, taking with them the skills that they have learned. According to endogenous growth theory those factors may be expected to have a determining effect on economic growth rates. Then there are activities such as education and medical care that are directed at the welfare of their clients but which have spin-off effects upon the community in terms of the benefits of living among healthy, well-educated people. Those externalities are held to justify some degree of subsidy, particularly as they may be expected to contribute to growth prospects. In principle, the criterion for each item of public investment is the satisfaction of a cost/benefit analysis criterion, with the amount of investment determined by the requirement that its marginal benefit should be equal to its marginal cost; and public investment that fails that test may be expected to reduce economic efficiency, as may failure to make investments that pass it. In practice, however, the necessary information may be uncertain or unavailable. In practice, also, the total amount of government expenditure may be limited by a budgetary constraint. If public expenditure exceeds the revenue from taxation, the resulting budget deficit has to be financed by borrowing. As noted in the above paragraph on current stabilisation policies, the tendency for deficits to increase during a recession in demand provides a contribution to the maintenance of stability. The resulting cyclical deficit may be expected to be balanced by a budgetary surplus during the cycle's recovery phase, leaving the total of the national debt unchanged. However, it is generally feared that a non-cyclical or structural deficit will have adverse long-term consequences, "crowding-out" private sector investment [22] , increasing taxation, and possibly raising the inflation rate. Although the evidence for those fears is somewhat uncertain, there is a widespread consensus that structural budget deficits should be limited and preferably avoided.

Taxation

There is evidence to suggest that taxation can reduce economic output and growth in a number of different ways. Redistributive taxes can reduce private savings and investment because the rich save more than the poor. Income tax and social security contributions can reduce employment and output because the difference that they create between what employers pay and what employees receive, reduces work incentives. Other taxes can distort supply and demand relationships in other markets to the detriment of economic efficiency. According to an OECD working paper [23], however, a review of published evidence indicates that “the effects of taxes on economic performance are ambiguous in some areas and unsettled and controversial in others” The only unequivocal policy conclusion that emerges from the evidence is that economic performance is best served by taxes that do not distort incentives, such as a poll tax or a tax on land values.

Regulation

In most countries, regulatory policy has significant positive and negative effects upon economic efficiency, output and growth. On the positive side is the basic framework of laws, regulations and codes of practice without which economic activity on the modern scale would not be possible. Without an effective system of law-enforcement and an accepted way of settling disputes,for example, much activity would be diverted from production and exchange into defence against violence. Also on the positive side are measures to promote competition, either by removing barriers, as in the case of antitrust or competition policy, or by providing consumers with information that they would otherwise lack, as in the case of product standards. Growth may also be facilitated by systems of patent law that provide incentives to innovation that might otherwise be lacking. Offsetting the benefits in every case are the costs to companies and individuals of complying with the regulations. On the negative side as far as macroeconomic considerations are concerned, are regulations that yield no economic benefit, and those whose costs exceed their benefits. Among them are regulations that prohibit innovation on the grounds of the mere possibility of harm – as advocated in the more extreme interpretations of the precautionary principle – and safety regulations that are based upon mistaken estimates of the negative value of the events against which they guard[24] .

Dissenting views

Among dissenting views are those of:

  • economists of the Austrian School who consider the economy to be too complex to justify the use of macroeconomic aggregates, and who use logical deductions from axioms rather than induction from economic statistics;
  • sustainability advocates who favour restricting or halting economic growth in order to preserve resources for the use of future generations;

References

  1. For a diagrammatic representation of the model, see the tutorials subpage
  2. For a definition of National income, see the article on Gross Domestic Product
  3. Quantity Theory of Money (CEPA)
  4. Friedman and Meiselman The relative stability of monetary velocity and the Investment Multiplier in the United States 1897-1958 in Stabilisation Policies, CMC Research Papers p165 Prentice-Hall 1964
  5. The development of monetarism (CEPA)
  6. GK Shaw Rational Expectations, Wheatsheaf Books, Harvester Press 1984
  7. A W H Phillips "The Relation Between Unemployment and the Rate of Change of Money Wages in the UK 1861-1951 Economica November 1958.
  8. Milton Friedman: Inflation and Unemployment Nobel Memorial Lecture 1976
  9. See K A Christal Controversies in British Macroeconomics George Allen and Unwin 1958 for a diagrammatic exposition
  10. Martin Prachowny "Okun's Law: Theoretical Foundations and Revised Estimates". The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 75, No. 2. (May, 1993), pp. 331-336
  11. Tim Congdon: "Two Concepts of the Output Gap", World Economics vol 9 n'Jan-Mar 2008
  12. Estimating the output gap. UK Office of Budget Responsibility, April 2011
  13. Izabella Kaminska, Why the UK output gap could be a chasm, FT Alphaville, Oct 4 2012
  14. see R J Barro and H Grossman Money, Employment and Inflation Cambridge University Press 1976
  15. H G Johnson International Trade and Economic Growth chapter 6 George Allen and Unwin 1958
  16. Nick Gardner Decade of Discontent pp 205-207 Basil Blackwell 1987
  17. Milton Friedman "A Monetary and Fiscal Framework for Economic Stability" in Essays in Positive Economics Phoenix Books 1966
  18. Fiscal Policy as a Countercyclical Tool, IMF World Economic Outlook, Chapter 5, October 2008
  19. Charles Bean Is There a Consensus in Monetary Policy?
  20. John B Taylor "Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice", in Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy no 39 1993 [1]
  21. Stanford University Monetary Policy Rule Homepage
  22. OECD Economic Studies No. 4, Spring 1985 - Budget Deficits and Crowding-out
  23. Leibfritz et al, OECD Working Paper No. 176 1997 Taxation and Economic Performance
  24. Aaron Wildavsky Searching for Safety Transaction Publishers , 1988