Welfare economics: Difference between revisions
imported>Stephen Saletta |
imported>Stephen Saletta No edit summary |
||
Line 3: | Line 3: | ||
[[Economics]] is both a ''positive science'' and a ''normative science''. Economics as a '''positive science''' studies how markets and economies work, regardless of whether or not those institutions produce a desirable result. '''Welfare economics''' is the '''normative''' study of the types of outcomes that an economic system ''should'' be producing, and whether or not those outcomes are being produced.<ref>Hirshleifer, J and Hirshleifer, D (1997) ''Price Theory and Applications'' ISBN 0131907786</ref> | [[Economics]] is both a ''positive science'' and a ''normative science''. Economics as a '''positive science''' studies how markets and economies work, regardless of whether or not those institutions produce a desirable result. '''Welfare economics''' is the '''normative''' study of the types of outcomes that an economic system ''should'' be producing, and whether or not those outcomes are being produced.<ref>Hirshleifer, J and Hirshleifer, D (1997) ''Price Theory and Applications'' ISBN 0131907786</ref> | ||
=== | ===The problem of interpersonal utility comparisons=== | ||
Welfare economics addresses the issue of interpersonal utility comparisons by using observations about consumption as a vector of choices rather than a utilitarian summation of the utility they derive from a particular consumption bundle. When making comparisons between more than one individual, a particular allocation of resources is '''pareto-optimal''' if you could not make one individual better off without making another person worse off. | |||
===Fundamental theorems of welfare economics=== | |||
In a market mechanism with flexible prices, individuals will continue to trade with each other until they reach an optimal outcome. The market provides a mechanism for individuals to communicate their preferences through prices so that each individual will be able to an optimal bundle of consumption given a particular budget constraint. | |||
====First theorem of Welfare Economics==== | |||
In a market with many traders where prices are flexible, any equilibrium will be pareto-optimal. | |||
====Second theorem of Welfare Economics==== | |||
Every outcome that is pareto-optimal can be realized in a market with many traders and flexible prices provided an appropriate initial distribution of endowments. | |||
==References== | ==References== | ||
<references/> | <references/> |
Revision as of 14:50, 28 November 2007
Economics is both a positive science and a normative science. Economics as a positive science studies how markets and economies work, regardless of whether or not those institutions produce a desirable result. Welfare economics is the normative study of the types of outcomes that an economic system should be producing, and whether or not those outcomes are being produced.[1]
The problem of interpersonal utility comparisons
Welfare economics addresses the issue of interpersonal utility comparisons by using observations about consumption as a vector of choices rather than a utilitarian summation of the utility they derive from a particular consumption bundle. When making comparisons between more than one individual, a particular allocation of resources is pareto-optimal if you could not make one individual better off without making another person worse off.
Fundamental theorems of welfare economics
In a market mechanism with flexible prices, individuals will continue to trade with each other until they reach an optimal outcome. The market provides a mechanism for individuals to communicate their preferences through prices so that each individual will be able to an optimal bundle of consumption given a particular budget constraint.
First theorem of Welfare Economics
In a market with many traders where prices are flexible, any equilibrium will be pareto-optimal.
Second theorem of Welfare Economics
Every outcome that is pareto-optimal can be realized in a market with many traders and flexible prices provided an appropriate initial distribution of endowments.
References
- ↑ Hirshleifer, J and Hirshleifer, D (1997) Price Theory and Applications ISBN 0131907786